1912 yilgacha bo'lgan Xitoyning iqtisodiy tarixi - Economic history of China before 1912

A circular, bulbous-disc-shaped golden canteen engraved with designs of a dragon and clouds, with a built-on stand and a cylindrical top that has a chain-link handle
A Xitoy ajdaho a ustida o'yilgan bulutlar orasida suzib yurganini ko'rdi Ming -era oltin oshxonasi (15-asr).

The Xitoyning iqtisodiy tarixi minglab yillarni qamrab oladi va mintaqa o'zgaruvchan rivojlanish va pasayish davrlarini boshidan kechirmoqda. Xitoy, so'nggi ikki ming yillikda, dunyodagi eng yirik va eng rivojlangan iqtisodiyotlardan biri edi.[1][2][3] Iqtisodiy tarixchilar odatda Xitoy tarixini uch davrga ajratadilar: imperiya davridan oldin paydo bo'lgan davrgacha Qin; erta imperiya davri Qindan to to yuksalishigacha Qo'shiq (221 Miloddan avvalgi 960 gachaIdoralar); va so'nggi imperiya davri, Song dan to yiqilish ning Qing.

Neolitik qishloq xo'jaligi Xitoyda taxminan 8000 ga qadar rivojlangan ediMiloddan avvalgi. Tabaqalangan Bronza davri kabi madaniyatlar Erlitou, uchinchi ming yillikda paydo bo'lganMiloddan avvalgi. Ostida Shang (16–11-asrlar)Miloddan avvalgi) va G'arbiy Chjou (11–8-asrlar)Miloddan avvalgi), qaram[tushuntirish kerak ] ishchi kuchi elita uchun bronza va ipak ishlab chiqarish uchun yirik quyma korxonalarda va ustaxonalarda ishladi. Tomonidan ishlab chiqarilgan qishloq xo'jaligi profitsiti yodgorlik iqtisodiyoti ularni erta qo'llab-quvvatladi hunarmandchilik sanoat tarmoqlari, shuningdek shahar markazlari va katta qo'shinlar. Ushbu tizim qulashi bilan parchalanishni boshladi G'arbiy Chjou 771 yildaMiloddan avvalgi, davomida Xitoy parchalanib ketgan Bahor va kuz (8-5 asrlar) Miloddan avvalgi) va Urushayotgan davlatlar davrlar (5–3-asrlar)Miloddan avvalgi).

Feodal tuzum qulashi bilan qonun chiqaruvchi hokimiyatning aksariyati dvoryanlardan mahalliy qirollarga o'tdi. Urushayotgan davlatlar davrida savdoning ko'payishi kuchli savdogar sinfini vujudga keltirdi. Yangi podshohlar urushlar olib borish, katta ibodatxonalar qurish va jamoat ishlari loyihalarini amalga oshirish uchun foydalanib, murakkab byurokratiyani o'rnatdilar. Bu meritokratik tizim iste'dodni tug'ilish huquqidan ustun qo'ydi. Temir asboblardan ko'proq foydalanish miloddan avvalgi 500 yildan boshlab qishloq xo'jaligida inqilob yuz berdi va bu davrda aholi sonining ko'payishiga olib keldi. 221 yildaMiloddan avvalgi, qiroli Qin o'zini e'lon qildi Birinchi imperator, Xitoyni birlashtirgan yagona imperiya, uning turli xil davlat devorlari Buyuk devor va uning turli xil xalqlari va an'analari yagona boshqaruv tizimiga aylandi.[4] Garchi ularni dastlabki amalga oshirish olib keldi uni ag'darish 206 yildaMiloddan avvalgi, Qin muassasalari omon qoldi. Davomida Xan sulolasi (Miloddan avvalgi 206-miloddan-220 yilgacha), Xitoy o'zini o'zi ta'minlaydigan dehqonlar va hunarmandlarning kuchli, birlashgan va markazlashgan imperiyasiga aylandi, mahalliy avtonomiyalar cheklangan edi.

The Qo'shiq davri (960-1279 AD / CE) qo'shimcha iqtisodiy islohotlarni olib keldi. Qog'oz pullar, kompas va boshqa texnologik yutuqlar keng miqyosda aloqani va kitoblarning keng tarqalishini osonlashtirdi. Davlatning iqtisodiyotni nazorati susayib, xususiy savdogarlar gullab-yashnashi va investitsiyalar va foydalarning katta o'sishiga imkon berdi. Davomida uzilishlarga qaramay Mo'g'ullarning 1279 yildagi istilosi, Qora vabo 14-asrda va keng ko'lamli isyonlar unga ergashgan Xitoy aholisi Kolumbiya birjasi va ostida juda ko'paydi Ming (Milodiy 1368-1644 yillar). Iqtisodiyot tomonidan qayta ko'rib chiqildi Yapon va Janubiy Amerika qaramay, tashqi savdo orqali olib kelingan kumush umuman izolyatsiya siyosati. Evropa va Xitoyning aksariyat davridagi nisbiy iqtisodiy holati Qing (1644-1912 AD / CE) munozara mavzusi bo'lib qolmoqda,[n 1] lekin a Katta farq 19-asrda aniq bo'lgan,[7] tomonidan itarilgan Sanoat va Texnologik inqiloblar.[8]

Imperialgacha bo'lgan davr

By Neolitik hozirgi paytda yashaydigan qabilalar Sariq daryo vodiy mashq qilar edi qishloq xo'jaligi. Uchinchi ming yillikdaMiloddan avvalgi, tabaqalashtirilgan Bronza davri jamiyatlar paydo bo'ldi, eng muhimi Erlitou madaniyati. Erlitou shimoliy Xitoyda hukmronlik qilgan va ular bilan aniqlangan Sya sulolasi, birinchi sulola an'anaviy ravishda Xitoy tarixshunosligi. Erlitudan keyin Shang va Chjou sulolalari, rivojlangan a yodgorlik iqtisodiyoti shunga o'xshash o'rta asrlarning G'arbiy Evropasi.[n 2] Oxiriga kelib Bahor va kuz davri, bu tizim qulay boshladi va uning o'rnida o'zini o'zi ta'minlaydigan dehqonlar va hunarmandlarning rivojlangan iqtisodiyoti o'rnini egalladi Urushayotgan davlatlar davri. Ushbu transformatsiya qachon tugallandi Qin davlati birlashgan Xitoy 221 yildaMiloddan avvalgi, Xitoy tarixining imperiya davrini boshlagan.[11][12]

Neolit ​​va dastlabki bronza asrlari

Qishloq xo'jaligi deyarli 10 mingdan boshlandi yil avval zamonaviy Xitoyning bir nechta mintaqalarida.[13] Eng qadimgi uy sharoitidagi ekinlar bo'lgan tariq shimolda va guruch janubda.[14][15] Ba'zi Neolitik madaniyatlarda qo'lda ishlaydigan to'qimachilik mahsulotlari ishlab chiqarilgan shpindel-vorllar 5000 dan ertaMiloddan avvalgi.[16] Eng qadimgi kashf etilgan ipak uchinchi ming yillikning boshiga to'g'ri keladiMiloddan avvalgi.[17] Shimoliy Xitoy tomonidan Longshan madaniyati (3 ming yillik)Miloddan avvalgi), tabaqalashgan ijtimoiy tuzilmalarga ega bo'lgan ko'plab jamoalar paydo bo'ldi.[18]

The Erlitou madaniyati (v. 1900-1350 Miloddan avvalgi), zamonaviy turdagi sayt nomi bilan nomlangan Xenan, ikkinchi ming yillikning boshlarida shimoliy Xitoyda hukmronlik qildiMiloddan avvalgi,[19][20] qachon shahar jamiyatlari va bronza Kasting birinchi bo'lib maydonda paydo bo'ldi.[21] The sigirlar, qalay, yashma va Erlituda ko'milgan firuza ularning ko'plab qo'shnilari bilan savdo qilishlarini taxmin qilmoqda.[22] Binolarning poydevorli poydevorlarini qurish uchun katta ishchi kuchi talab qilinadi.[22] Juda tabaqalashgan bo'lsa ham[23] Erlitu jamiyati hech qanday yozuv qoldirmadi, ba'zi tarixchilar buni afsonaviy deb topdilar Sya sulolasi an'anaviy xitoy yozuvlarida Shangdan oldingi sifatida qayd etilgan.[24][19]

Faqat boy elita boshchiligidagi kuchli markazlashgan davlat bronza bronza ishlab chiqarishi mumkin edi Erligang madaniyati (v. 15-chi–XIV asrlarMiloddan avvalgi).[23] Ularning holati, qaysi Bagli "Sharqiy Osiyoning birinchi buyuk tsivilizatsiyasi" deb nomlagan,[25] bronzalarni import qilgan qo'shni davlatlar yoki ularni tashlashi mumkin bo'lgan hunarmandlar bilan o'zaro aloqada bo'lgan.[26] Ushbu almashinuvlar bronza metallurgiya texnikasining tarqalishiga imkon berdi.[23] Ba'zi tarixchilar Erligangni Shang joyi deb aniqladilar, chunki u an'anaviy manbalarda Shang faol bo'lgan degan maydonga to'g'ri keladi, ammo bu identifikatsiyani tasdiqlaydigan yozma manbalar mavjud emas.[27]

Shang sulolasi (taxminan 1600 - taxminan 1045)Miloddan avvalgi)

Birinchi sayt shubhasiz Shang sulolasi tomonidan zamondosh yozuvlar bu Anyang, 1200 atrofida yirik aholi punktiga aylangan Shang poytaxtiMiloddan avvalgi.[26] Shangning asosiy ekinlari, asosan qishloq xo'jaligi jamiyati edi tariq,[28] lekin guruch va bug'doy ham etishtirildi[29] qirol zodagonlariga tegishli bo'lgan maydonlarda. Qirollik dalalari tomonidan ishlab chiqarilgan qishloq xo'jaligi profitsiti Shanx qirol oilasi va hukmron elitani, rivojlangan hunarmandchilik sanoatini (bronza, ipak va boshqalarni) va katta qo'shinlarni qo'llab-quvvatladi.[30] Katta qirol yaylovlari hayvonlarni ta'minlagan qurbonliklar va go'shtni iste'mol qilish.[31] Boshqa qishloq xo'jaligi mahsulotlari Shanxol aholisini qo'llab-quvvatladi, ularning taxminiy soni 5,5 dan 8 milliongacha.[32]

Bo'sh qoldirilguncha erlar faqat bir necha yil davomida ishlanganligi sababli, doimiy ravishda yangi erlarni ochish kerak edi[33] tomonidan drenaj past maydonlarni yoki tozalash orqali skrubland yoki o'rmonlar.[34] Ushbu vazifalar tomonidan bajarilgan majburiy mehnat davlat nazorati ostida,[33] ko'pincha ov ekspeditsiyalari doirasida.[35]

Neolit ​​davridagi avvalgilar singari, Shang ham shpindel g'ildiraklaridan foydalangan holda to'qimachilik buyumlarini ishlab chiqargan, ammo Shang ishchi kuchi rasman tashkil qilingan.[36] Shanxay vaqtga kelib, nazorat ostida ishchilar zodagonlarga mo'ljallangan ustaxonalarda ipak ishlab chiqarganlar.[37] Maydonlar va ustaxonalar turli darajadagi servitutlar mehnatidan iborat edi.[38] Ba'zi tarixchilar bu qaram ishchilarni "qullar "va Shangni" qullar jamiyati "deb belgilagan, ammo boshqalar bunday yorliqlarni juda noaniq deb rad etishadi, chunki biz ushbu ishchi kuchining mohiyati haqida juda kam ma'lumotga egamiz.[39]

G'arbiy Chjou sulolasi (taxminan 1045 - 771)Miloddan avvalgi)

An'anaviy tanishish bo'yicha Chjou sulolasi 1045 yil atrofida Shangni mag'lub etdiMiloddan avvalgi va nazoratini o'z qo'liga oldi Vey va Sariq daryo Shang hukmronlik qilgan vodiylar. Er qirol oilasiga qarashli bo'lib, uni qaramog'idagi kishilar orasida qayta taqsimlagan tizim ko'pgina tarixchilar (shubhali)[9] feodal tashkilotiga o'xshatilgan ning o'rta asrlar Evropa. Epigrafik dalillar shuni ko'rsatadiki, X asr oxirlaridaMiloddan avvalgi Hali ham ko'rib chiqilmagan bo'lsa-da, er sotilmoqda xususiy mulk.[40][41] Shahesnessy er almashinuvidagi bu o'sish elita nasablarining filiallarga bo'linishi va uning ta'minoti kamayib borayotgan paytda erga bo'lgan talabning ortishi natijasida yuzaga kelganligi haqidagi gipotezalar.[42]

4-asr Mencius erta Chjou rivojlangan deb da'vo qilmoqda maydon maydonlari tizimi,[n 3] sakkizta dehqon oilasi xo'jayin uchun dehqonchilik qilgan markaziy uchastka atrofida dalalarni o'stiradigan erlarni egallash uslubi.[44] Zamonaviy tarixchilar odatda ushbu idealizatsiya tizimining mavjudligidan shubhalanishdi,[45][46] ammo ba'zilari, qaramog'ida bo'lganida, bu Chjou boshida norasmiy ravishda mavjud bo'lishi mumkin edi ijarachilar pullik obidalarda ishlash corvee keyinroq bo'lgani kabi ijara o'rniga ularning egalariga.[47] Ko'pgina xitoylik tarixchilar buni tarixiy deb ta'riflashda davom etmoqdalar.[48]

To'qimachilik, bronza va qurol-yarog 'ishlab chiqarish kabi Shang davrida rivojlangan qo'l san'atlari Chjou davrida ham davom ettirildi, ammo butunlay davlat tomonidan boshqarildi. Chjou hukumati shuningdek, ko'pgina savdo-sotiq va almashinuvni tayinlash orqali boshqargan jia, keyinchalik unvoni har qanday savdogar ma'nosida ishlatilgan amaldorlar.[49]

Bahor va kuz davri (771–475)Miloddan avvalgi)

Five elongated bronze knives, corroded over time with a green color, with a ring handle on the end opposite the blade
Bronza pichoq pul qadimdan Yan

Chjou qulashi boshlandi Bahor va kuz davri nomi bilan nomlangan Konfutsiy ' Bahor va kuzgi yilnomalar. Ilgari yarim feodal tuzum tanazzulga uchragan va savdo rivojlana boshlagan davlatlar o'rtasida urush davri bo'lgan. Shtatlar o'rtasidagi raqobat tez texnologik taraqqiyotga olib keldi. Temir qurollar Qishloq xo'jaligi profitsiti ishlab chiqarilib, ilgari dalalar tizimida mavjud bo'lgan barcha narsalar tugadi. Bu davr oxiriga kelib temir texnologiyasining joriy etilishi feodal tuzumning to'liq qulashiga olib keldi va yangi rivojlanish davrini boshlab berdi.[50] Ushbu davrdagi xitoylik rivojlanish elementarlikning birinchi izolatsiyasini o'z ichiga oldi oltingugurt oltinchi asrdaMiloddan avvalgi.[51]

Bahor va kuz davrida ko'plab shaharlar hajmi va aholisi o'sdi. Linzi, obod poytaxti Qi, 650 yilda 200 mingdan ziyod aholi istiqomat qilganMiloddan avvalgi, uni dunyodagi eng yirik shaharlardan biriga aylantiradi.[iqtibos kerak ] Boshqa yirik shaharlar qatorida Linzi ma'muriyat markazi bo'lib xizmat qilgan, savdo va iqtisodiy faoliyat. Shaharlarning aksariyati shug'ullangan chorvachilik va shu tariqa o'zini o'zi ta'minlaydilar. Ushbu shaharlarning o'sishi qadimgi Xitoy iqtisodiyoti uchun muhim voqea bo'ldi.[52]

Keng ko'lamli savdo savdogarlar davlatlar o'rtasida tovarlarni tashish paytida bahor va kuz davrida boshlandi. Katta miqdorda valyuta tijoratni joylashtirish uchun chiqarilgan. Garchi ba'zi davlatlar savdoni cheklab qo'ygan bo'lsa-da, boshqalari uni rag'batlantirgan. Zheng Xitoyning markazida va'da berdi savdogarlarni tartibga solmaslik. Zheng savdogarlari butun Xitoy bo'ylab kuchli bo'ldi Yan shimoldan to Chu janubda.[53]

Katta feodal mulklar parchalanib ketdi, bu jarayon qachon tezlashdi Lu soliq tizimini 594 yilda o'zgartirdiMiloddan avvalgi. Yangi qonunlarga ko'ra, don ishlab chiqaruvchilarga har bir zodagonlardan olinadigan teng miqdordan emas, balki ishlov beriladigan er miqdori bo'yicha soliq solindi. Boshqa davlatlar ulardan o'rnak olishdi.[54] Erkin dehqonlar aholining ko'pchiligiga aylanib, markazlashgan davlatlar uchun soliq bazasini ta'minladilar.

Urushayotgan davlatlar davri (475–221)Miloddan avvalgi)

The Urushayotgan davlatlar davri tezkor texnologik yutuqlar va falsafiy rivojlanishlarni ko'rdi. Hukmdorlar bir-birlarining erlarini boshqarish uchun raqobatlashar ekan, ular turli xil islohotlarni amalga oshirdilar va Xitoyning iqtisodiy tizimini tubdan o'zgartirdilar. Oddiy tug'ilgan er egalari va savdogarlar gullab-yashnab, qolgan zodagonlar ta'sirini yo'qotdilar. Kabi ba'zi savdogarlar, masalan Lü Buvey, kichik davlatlar kabi boy bo'lgan bo'lishi mumkin.[55]

Davlat tomonidan homiylik qilingan quyma korxonalar hamma joyda temirdan yasalgan asbob-uskunalarni yasashgan;[iqtibos kerak ] temir shudgor, zaytun ho'kizlari, qatorda kultivatsiya va intensiv ilgaklar joriy etildi.[56] Quyma temir 4-asr davomida Xitoyda ixtiro qilinganMiloddan avvalgi.[iqtibos kerak ] Eng yirik temir zavodlarini boshqargan hukumatlar feodallar hisobiga davlatlarni mustahkamlab, harbiy texnika monopoliyasini rivojlantirdilar. Temir qishloq xo'jaligi qurollari ortiqcha qishloq xo'jalik mahsulotlarini ko'paytirishga imkon berdi.[57]

Keyin Shan Yang 3-asrdagi islohotlarMiloddan avvalgi, erni sotib olish va sotish mumkin, bu qishloq xo'jaligida iqtisodiy taraqqiyotni va hosildorlikni oshirishni rag'batlantirdi.[58] Yangi qudratli davlatlar kabi yirik sug'orish loyihalarini amalga oshirdilar Chjenguo kanali va Dujiangyan sug'orish tizimi. Oldin xarob bo'lgan katta miqdordagi erlar ishlab chiqarilib, Tsin iqtisodiyotiga qo'shildi. Qishloq xo'jaligining yuksalishi katta qo'shinlarga imkon berdi.

Bu davrda davlatning tobora kuchayib borayotgan kuchi monarxiyani kuchaytirdi, unga monarx hokimiyatini mustahkamlash uchun islohotlarni amalga oshirishga imkon berdi. Ushbu keng qamrovli islohotlar Qin tomonidan amalga oshirildi Shan Yang jumladan, feodal zodagonlarni bekor qilish, dvoryanlarning erlarini harbiy xizmatga qarab qayta taqsimlash va erga xususiy mulkchilikka ruxsat berish. U tinch bo'lmagan erlarni etishtirishni rag'batlantirdi, jangda yaxshi natijalarga erishgan askarlarga olijanob darajalar berdi va samarali va qat'iy huquqiy kod. Mutlaq monarxiya Song va Min sulolalari ostida asta-sekin zaiflashguncha Xitoyda davom etdi.[59]

Dastlabki imperiya davri

Dastlabki imperiya davri kuchli, birlashgan va markazlashgan monarxiya bilan ajralib turardi, ammo mahalliy amaldorlar hali ham cheklangan muxtoriyatni saqlab qolishgan. Dastlabki imperiya davrida o'zini o'zi ta'minlaydigan dehqonlar va hunarmandlar iqtisodiyotda hukmronlik qildilar va asosan umumiy bozordan mustaqil ravishda faoliyat yuritdilar. Savdo nisbatan tez-tez bo'lib, Xan sulolasidan keyin rivojlanishi bilan kuchayib bordi ipak yo'l The Vu Xu qo'zg'oloni iqtisodiyotni cho'loq,[60] Tanggacha tiklanmadi, uning ostida u Song va Min sulolalarining savdo-sotiq iqtisodiyotiga aylandi.

Tsin sulolasi (221–206)Miloddan avvalgi)

221 yildaMiloddan avvalgi, Tsin shtati Xitoyda qolgan davlatlarni zabt etdi va olimlar fikricha birinchi birlashgan Xitoy davlati.[4] U tezda kengayib, janubiy chegarani kengaytirdi Yangtsi zamonaviyga Vetnam va shimoliy chegara zamonaviygacha Mo'g'uliston. Dastlabki Sya, Shan va Chjou sulolalari butun Xitoy ustidan nominal hokimiyatga ega bo'lgan bo'lsa, feodal tuzum aksariyat mintaqalarga katta avtonomiyalar berdi. Ammo Tsin ostida markazlashgan davlat barpo etildi,[4] va butun imperiya savdoni engillashtirish uchun yagona standartlarga va valyutaga ega edi. Bundan tashqari, Qin hukumati shunga o'xshash ko'plab jamoat ishlari loyihalarini amalga oshirdi Buyuk Xitoy devori. Tsin Vu Xu qo'zg'oloniga qadar davom etgan "birinchi Xitoy imperiyasi" deb nomlangan ishni boshlagan.

Tsin imperatori yozuvlar, vaznni o'lchash va g'ildirak uzunligini birlashtirgan standartlar, shu bilan birga davlatlar o'rtasida turlicha bo'lgan eski valyutalarni bekor qildi. Shuningdek, u butun imperiya bo'ylab yagona qonunlar kodeksini chiqardi, bu esa savdoni engillashtirdi. Savdoga xalaqit bergani sababli davlatlar o'rtasidagi mudofaa devorlari buzib tashlandi. Tsin imperiyasi eski feodal tuzumga qaytmadi, balki 36 kishilik tizimni o'rnatdi buyruqlar, har biri bir qatorni boshqaradi okruglar.[4] Qinning boshqa siyosatlari, shu jumladan tuz va temir ishlab chiqaruvchilarga og'ir soliqqa tortish va ko'plab xitoyliklarning janubiy va g'arbdagi yangi hududlarga majburiy ko'chishi.

Tsin hukumati ko'plab jamoat ishlarini amalga oshirdi, ishchilar ko'pincha soliq qarzini to'lash uchun davlat tomonidan majburan chaqiriladilar. Ushbu loyihalarning eng mashhuri bu Buyuk Xitoy devori, davlatni himoya qilish uchun qurilgan Xionnu hujumlar. Boshqa Qin loyihalariga quyidagilar kiradi Lingqu kanali Yantszi va Pearl daryolarining sho'ba korxonalarini bir-biriga bog'lab, Qinning janubiy istilosini amalga oshirishga imkon bergan,[61] shuningdek, 4250 milya (6,840 km) ga baholangan keng yo'l tizimi.[62]

Biroq, Qinning huquqshunos qonunlar va uning soliqlari va soliqlarining og'ir yuki imperiyaning qolgan qismi tomonidan osonlikcha qabul qilinmadi. Boshqa davlatlardan farqli o'laroq, Qin savdogarlarni surgun qilish va ularning boyliklarini ekspluatatsiya qilish, shuningdek tuz, temir, o'rmon va boshqa tabiiy boyliklarga monopoliyalarni yuklash to'g'risida qonunlar qabul qildi. Olimlar ta'kidlashlaricha, taniqli savdogarlar ro'yxati Urushayotgan davlatlar tuzilgan Sima Qian Xan sulolasi davrida bo'lgan Shiji (Buyuk tarix) Tsinning bitta savdogarini o'z ichiga olmaydi.[63] Isyonlar vafotidan ko'p o'tmay sodir bo'lgan birinchi Qin imperatori va 206 yilga kelibMiloddan avvalgi, Qin qulab tushdi.[61]

Xan sulolasi (206Miloddan avvalgi – 220 Idoralar)

A flat, silk brocade with black and red colors woven in a geometric pattern
To'qilgan ipak 1-sonli qabrdan to'qimachilik Mavangdui Xan maqbaralari joylashgan joy, Xitoyning Xunan viloyati, Changsha, G'arbiy Xan sulolasiga tegishli, 2-asrMiloddan avvalgi

The Xan sulolasi Xitoyning birinchisi sifatida esga olinadi Oltin asrlar. Xan ostida eng yuqori darajaga yetdi Imperator Vu (Miloddan avvalgi 141-87), kim Xionnuni bo'ysundirdi va nazoratini o'z qo'liga oldi Hexi yo'lagi, ochish Ipak yo'li miloddan avvalgi 121 yilda. Ro'yxatdan o'tgan 58 million aholiga ega bo'lgan Xan davrida iqtisodiyot jadal rivojlandi. Yirik korxonalar paydo bo'ldi, ba'zilari keyinchalik G'arbiy Xan davrida vaqtincha milliylashtirildi. Kabi texnologik yangiliklar aravachasi, qog'oz va a seysmograf, bu davrda ixtiro qilingan.[64]

G'arbiy Xan sulolasi

Imperatorlar hukmronligi Wen (Miloddan avvalgi 180-157) va Jing (Miloddan avvalgi 157-141) tinchlik va farovonlik davri bo'lgan. Ularning hukmronligi davrida iqtisodiyotni davlat tomonidan nazorat qilish quyidagicha kuzatilgan Daosist printsipi Vu Vey (無為), "harakatsiz harakat" ma'nosini anglatadi.[65] Ularning bir qismi sifatida laissez-faire Qishloq xo'jaligi soliqlari qishloq xo'jaligi mahsulotlarining 1/15 qismidan 1/30 gacha qisqartirildi va qisqa muddatgacha butunlay bekor qilindi. Bundan tashqari, mehnat corvee dehqonlardan talab har yili 1 oydan uch yilda bir oygacha kamaytirildi.[66][67] Tangalarni zarb qilish xususiylashtirildi.[68]

Bu davrda ham xususiy, ham davlat sektori rivojlandi. Imperator Jing ostida,

... tangalar sumkalarini osib qo'yishda ishlatiladigan arqonlar og'irligi tufayli uzilib ketar, bir necha yil davomida saqlanib kelingan don sumkalari qarovsiz qoldirilib yemaganligi sababli chirigan edi.[69]

Jinoyatchining burnini kesib olish kabi og'ir jinoiy jazolar bekor qilindi.[67]

Xan soliq tizimi ikki soliqqa asoslangan edi; er mulk solig'i va a ovoz berish solig'i. O'rtacha jismoniy shaxsning soliq yuki quruqlikdagi mahsulotning o'ttizdan bir qismidan va har bir kishi uchun 7 tadan 14 yoshgacha bo'lgan 20 tangadan iborat soliq solig'idan iborat bo'lib, 14 yoshdan yuqori bo'lganlar uchun yana bir soliq solig'i bilan. Xan sulolasining oxirlarida, soliq stavkasi chunki qishloq xo'jaligi yuzdan biriga qisqartirildi, yo'qolgan daromad so'rovga oshirilgan soliqlar hisobiga qoplandi.[70] Savdogarlar ikki baravar stavka bo'yicha haq olindi. Soliq tizimining yana bir muhim tarkibiy qismi Corvee ishi edi. Har bir mehnatga layoqatli erkak, sog'lig'i 20 dan yuqori bo'lgan erkak sifatida belgilangan, ikki yillik harbiy xizmat yoki bir oylik harbiy xizmat va bir yillik mehnat mehnatiga haqli edi (keyinchalik 56 yoshdan yuqori bo'lganlar har qanday harbiy yoki harbiy xizmatdan ozod qilingan) ).[71]

Boshqa tomondan, imperator Vu urushlari uchun pul to'lash uchun iqtisodiyotga aralashganida munozaralarni keltirib chiqardi. Uning aralashuvi islohotchilar o'rtasida qizg'in bahs-munozaralar bo'lib o'tdi, ular asosan konfessiyaviy olimlar, laisse-faire siyosatini ma'qullaydigan va modernistlar, tuz va temirga nisbatan davlat monopoliyalarini qo'llab-quvvatlagan hukumat amaldorlari guruhi va imperator Vu kashshof bo'lgan yuqori soliq siyosati.[72] Ushbu bahslar kitobga yozib qo'yilgan Tuz va temirga oid ma'ruzalar, qadimiy Xitoy iqtisodiy fikrini ko'rsatadigan muhim hujjat. Imperator Vudan keyin modernistik siyosat G'arbiy Xanning aksariyat qismida kuzatilgan bo'lsa-da, islohotchilar Sharqiy Xondagi bu siyosatlarni bekor qildilar, faqat hukumat tanga zarb qilish monopoliyasidan tashqari.[73]

Xan sanoati

A green-glazed ceramic statuette of a dog with pointy ears and curly tail, standing upright on all fours with eyes open
Xan maqbarasidan bezak kiyib olgan sopol idish itning yoqasi; sopol haykalchalar ishlab chiqarish qabristonning keyingi hayoti uchun bunday mahsulotlar ishlab chiqaradigan dafn sanoatining muhim qismini tashkil etdi.

G'arbiy Xanning dastlabki davrida imperiyada eng boy odamlar tuz va temir ishlab chiqaradigan va tarqatadigan savdogarlar edi [74] va imperatorlik sudi tomonidan yig'iladigan yillik soliq tushumlari bilan raqobatdosh bo'lgan boylikka ega bo'ldi.[74] Ushbu savdogarlar erga sarmoya kiritib, buyuk er egalariga aylandilar va ko'p sonli dehqonlarni ish bilan ta'minladilar.[74] Suyuq sho'r suv, dengiz tuzi, tosh tuzi yoki temir rudalarini qazib olish uchun tuz yoki temir sanoati mingdan ortiq dehqonlarni jalb qilishi mumkin edi.[74] 4800 fut / 1440 gacha burg'ulashga imkon beradigan zamonaviy burg'ulash texnikasi metr xitoyliklarga tuz va hattoki qazib olishga imkon beruvchi ishlab chiqilgan tabiiy gaz yoqilg'i va yoritishda foydalanish uchun.[iqtibos kerak ]

Xan imperatori Vu (r. 141–87)Miloddan avvalgi) bunday yirik xususiy sanoat tarmoqlarini davlatga tahdid deb bilgan, chunki ular dehqonlar sadoqatini dehqonchilikdan va sanoatchilarga qaratgan.[74] Milliylashtirish tuz va temir savdolari bu tahdidni yo'q qildi va davlatga katta foyda keltirdi.[74] Ushbu siyosat imperator Vuning kengaytiruvchi maqsadlariga mos edi ko'chmanchi Xionnu Konfederatsiyasiga qarshi kurash mustamlaka paytida Hexi yo'lagi va hozirgi Markaziy Osiyo, Shimoliy Vetnam, Yunnan va Shimoliy Koreyaning Shinjon.[75] Tarixchi Donald Vagner Xan temir monopoliyasini ishlab chiqarish taxminan 5000 tonnani tashkil etganini taxmin qilmoqda (har bir temir idorasiga 100 tonnani nazarda tutgan holda),[76] noqonuniy xususiy ishlab chiqarish va undan keyin o'sish tufayli haqiqiy ko'rsatkich ancha yuqori edi xususiylashtirish Keyinchalik Xan ostida.[iqtibos kerak ]

Ushbu harakat tufayli ko'plab sanoatchilar bankrot bo'lishiga qaramay, hukumat sobiq savdogarlarni jalb qildi Sang Hongyang (vafot etgan 80 yilMiloddan avvalgi) milliy monopoliyalarni boshqarish.[74] Garchi suddagi siyosiy fraksiya markaziy hukumat monopoliyalari 44 dan 41 gacha bekor qilingan bo'lsa hamMiloddan avvalgi, monopoliyalar oxirigacha qayta tiklandi Vang Mang ning (9-23 r.)Idoralar) tartib.[77] Uni ag'darib tashlaganidan so'ng, markaziy hukumat ushbu tarmoqlarni nazorat qilishni xususiy ishbilarmonlarga topshirdi.[74][77]

Yana bir foydali tovar bo'lgan likyor ham hukumat tomonidan miloddan avvalgi 98 va 81 yillar oralig'ida milliylashtirildi. Xususiy mulkka qaytganidan so'ng, hukumat alkogolli savdogarlarga og'ir soliqlar qo'ydi.[78][79]

Shtatdagi qisqa muddatli monopoliyalardan tashqari, hukumat sud va armiya ehtiyojlarini ta'minlash uchun hunarmandchilik sanoatining alohida sektorini boshqargan;[80] Ushbu amaliyot Xitoy tarixida davom etdi, ammo keyinchalik ushbu sektorning ahamiyati pasayib ketdi Tang sulolasi.

To'qimachilik va kulolchilik kabi engil sanoat ham ushbu davrda sezilarli darajada rivojlandi. Xususan, qo'lda yasalgan sopol idishlar juda ko'p miqdorda tayyorlangan; uning narxi sezilarli darajada pasayib, Chjou paytida ishlatilgan bronza idishlarni almashtirishga imkon berdi. Ushbu davrda chinni ham paydo bo'ldi.[81]

Xan qishloq xo'jaligi

Ostida boshlangan temir qurollardan keng foydalanish Urushayotgan davlatlar davri Xitoy qishloq xo'jaligi samaradorligini oshirishga imkon berdi. Bularga "ikki tishli" shudgor va erta o'roq kiradi. Ikkita operatorni talab qiladigan ikkita qoramol va bitta operatsiyani talab qiladigan uchta qoramolli shudgorning kiritilishi bilan qoramollardan tortiladigan pulluklardan foydalanish yaxshilandi.[82] Yana bir muhim ixtiro, ilgari tomoq jabduqlaridan farqli o'laroq, otning yoqasi jabduqlarini ixtiro qilish edi. Ushbu yangilik, g'ildirakli aravachasi bilan bir qatorda, transport xarajatlarini keskin kamaytirish va uzoq masofali savdo-sotiqni amalga oshirish orqali Xitoy iqtisodiyotini birlashtirdi.

The urug 'ekish mashinasi bu davrda ham ishlab chiqilgan bo'lib, fermerlarga urug'larni tasodifiy chiqarib tashlash o'rniga aniq qatorlarda burish mumkin edi. Xan imperatori Vu davrida "Dai Tian Fa" ning dastlabki shakli almashlab ekish joriy etildi. Dehqonlar o'z erlarini ikki qismga bo'lishdi, ulardan biri ekiladi, ikkinchisi yaroqsiz qoladi.[82]

Xan savdosi va valyuta

Two circular bronze coins with square holes in the center which have been corroded over time with a green color
A usu (五 銖) hukmronligi davrida chiqarilgan tanga Imperator Vu (r. 141–87)Miloddan avvalgi), Diametri 25,5 mm

Imperator Vuning harbiy yurishlari va mustamlakachilik harakatlarini moliyalashtirish uchun foydalaniladigan daromad manbalariga erlarni zodagonlardan tortib olish, idoralar va unvonlarni sotish, tijorat soliqlarini ko'paytirish va hukumat chiqarilishi kiradi. tangalarni zarb qilish.[83] Markaziy hukumat ilgari xususiy qo'mondonlik darajasida va qirollik darajasidagi zarbxonalardan hokimiyatni olib, tanga zarb qilishni monopoliyalashtirishga urinib ko'rgan va muvaffaqiyatsiz bo'lgan.[84] 119 yildaMiloddan avvalgi markaziy hukumat usu (五 銖) 3,2 g (0,11 oz), va 113 ga teng tangaMiloddan avvalgi bu imperiyada qonuniy ravishda qabul qilingan yagona tanga bo'ldi, hukumat xususiy zarbxonalarni noqonuniy deb e'lon qildi.[73] Van Mang rejimi turli xil yangi, engil valyutalarni, shu jumladan arxaiklarni joriy qildi pichoq pul tangalarni qadrsizlantirgan. The usu tanga 40 yilda tiklanganIdoralar Sharqiy Xan asoschisi tomonidan, Imperator Guangvu va Tanglar sulolasiga qadar Xitoyning standart tangani bo'lib qoldi.[73][85][86]

Chet ellar bilan savdo keng miqyosda imperator Vu davrida boshlangan edi, u kashfiyotchi Chjan Yni ittifoqchilar izlash uchun Xitoyning g'arbidagi xalqlar bilan aloqa qilish uchun yubordi. xionnu bilan kurashish. Ammo Xionnu mag'lub bo'lganidan so'ng, Xitoy qo'shinlari o'zlarini o'rnatdilar Markaziy Osiyoda va G'arbiy mintaqalar, mashhurlarni boshlash Ipak yo'li xalqaro savdo-sotiqning asosiy xiyoboniga aylandi.[87]

Sin sulolasi

8 daIdoralar, Xanlar kansleri Vang Mang Xan imperatorlari taxtini egallab oldi va o'z xin sulolasini o'rnatdi. Van Mang xanlarni erta Chjuning "idil" holatiga qaytarishni xohlagan. U erlar va qullar savdosini qonuniylashtirmadi va ko'plab davlat monopoliyalarini tashkil etdi. Ushbu ultra-modernistik siyosat uni 25 yilda hokimiyatdan ag'darib, qatl etgan aholiga unchalik yoqmadiIdoralar va Xan sulolasini tikladi.[88]

Sharqiy Xan sulolasi

Van Mangning ag'darilishi ortidan ergashgan Sharqiy Xan sulolasi davrida laissez-faire siyosatlar tiklandi va hukumat harbiy xizmatni bekor qildi va iqtisodiyotni boshqarishdan voz kechdi. Deb nomlangan farovonlik va intellektual fikrlashning yangi davri Ming va Chjan qoidalari, boshlangan. Bu davrda buyuk olim tug'ildi, Chjan Xen va ixtirosi qog'oz.[89] Biroq, 2-asrning oxiriga kelib Xan jamiyati parchalana boshladi. 184 yilda dehqon voizi isyonni boshladi Sariq salla isyoni, bu Xan sulolasini nomidan tashqari hamma bilan tugatdi.[60]

Vey va Djin (220–304)

Shuningdek, Uch shohlik davr, the Vey va Jin Xanlar sulolasi qulaganidan keyin sodir bo'lgan davrlarda 150 yildan ortiq vaqt ichida birinchi marta Xitoyni keng miqyosdagi urush qamrab oldi. Qurbonlar soni va undan keyingi iqtisodiy zarar katta edi. Qudratli aristokratik er egalari ko'chib ketgan dehqonlarga boshpana berib, Qin va Xan davrida bekor qilingan imtiyozlarni qaytarib olish uchun o'zlarining kuchaygan vakolatlarini ishlatishdi. Ushbu qochqinlarga endi davlat soliq solmaydi. Jin davrida soliq solinadigan aholi 20 millionni tashkil etgan; Xanlar davrida bu 57 million edi. Shimoliy Xitoyning aksariyat qismi Vey sulolasiga asos solgan Cao Cao tomonidan birlashtirildi (220–265) va Tszin Xitoyning qolgan qismini 280 yilda birlashtirdi. Markazlashgan davlat yirik er egalari himoyasida bo'lganlarning soliq tushumidan mahrum bo'lib zaiflashdi.[60] Shunga qaramay, tashlandiq erlarni milliylashtirgan va dehqonlarga dehqonlar ustida ishlashni rag'batlantirishni buyurgan Cao Cao siyosati ostida iqtisodiyot biroz tiklandi,[90] shuningdek, Jin va Janubiy sulolalar davrida davom etadigan nafratlangan temir monopoliyasini qayta tiklash. Keyinchalik Sakkiz shahzodalar urushi, bu jinlarning barbarlarni harakatga keltirish siyosati bilan birlashganda Vu Xu ishchi kuchi etishmovchiligini yumshatish uchun Xitoyga kirib, oxir-oqibat Xitoyning qulashiga sabab bo'ldi.[91]

Vu Xu (304–420)

304 yilda Xitoy nazorati ostida bo'lgan barbar klanlarning katta qo'zg'oloni bo'lib o'tdi. Jin sulolasining turli shahzodalari o'rtasida bir necha yillik fuqarolar urushidan so'ng, boshchiligidagi Xyonnu Lyu Yuan, qo'zg'olon ko'tarib, Xitoydan mustaqilligini e'lon qildi. Keyinchalik Xitoy nazorati ostidagi boshqa bir qancha guruhlar, jumladan Jie, Tsian, Di va Sianbei. Ushbu guruhlar umumiy sifatida Vu Xu, Sariq daryo vodiysida xan xitoylariga qarshi genotsidni amalga oshirgan. Jinlar imperiyasining qulashi bu qo'zg'olonlardan so'ng tezda yuz berdi.[91] Vu Xu istilosi keng ko'lamli depopulyatsiyani keltirib chiqardi va Tsin, Xan, Vey va Tszin davrida rivojlangan bozor iqtisodiyotining tez pasayishiga olib keldi, bu feodal manorial iqtisodiyotining qayta tiklanishiga imkon berdi. Yirik yodgorlik mulklari o'zini o'zi ta'minlagan va keng bozordan ajralib qolgan. Ushbu mulklar qishloq xo'jaligi, chorvachilik, o'rmonchilik, baliq ovlash va hunarmandchilik buyumlarini ishlab chiqarish bilan shug'ullanadigan mustaqil iqtisodiyot edi. Ayirboshlash endi pul orqali emas, ayirboshlash orqali amalga oshirildi. Sui birlashgandan keyin iqtisodiy tiklanishdan so'ng, manorial iqtisodiyot yana pasayib ketdi.[92]

Qisqa iqtisodiy tiklanish ostida Shimoliy sodir Fu Jian, ning Di hukmdori Sobiq Qin, Shimoliy Xitoyni kim birlashtirdi. Fu Jian Xan va Tszin ostida qurilgan sug'orish loyihalarini ta'mirladi va har 20 kilometrda savdogarlar uchun mehmonxonalar va stantsiyalar tashkil etdi. Fu Tszyan hukmronligi davrida savdo va qishloq xo'jaligi sezilarli darajada jonlandi va ko'plab davlatlar yana jo'natildi o'lpon Fu Tszian sudiga.[93] Ushbu tiklanish Fu Jian mag'lub bo'lganda tugadi Fei jangi Jin kuchlari tomonidan uning imperiyasi bir qator kichik davlatlarga qulashiga sabab bo'ldi. Ushbu jang eng muhim janglardan biri hisoblanadi Xitoy tarixi chunki u Xitoy tsivilizatsiyasini halokat xavfidan saqlab qoldi.[94]

Ayni paytda, qonuniy Jin sulolasi janubga, keyin Xitoy imperiyasining rivojlanmagan atrofiga qochib ketgan edi. Jin hukmdorlari ushbu mintaqani boshqaruv markazi va o'z vatanlarini qaytarib olish uchun tayanch sifatida rivojlantirishga harakat qilishdi.[95] Jin hukmdorlari qo'zg'olondan oldin mavjud bo'lgan boshqaruv tizimini saqlab qolgan barbarlik hukmronligidan qochgan xitoylik muhojirlarga va er egalariga janubdagi katta erlarni berdilar. Shimoliy odamlarning ko'chishi janubiy iqtisodiyotni rag'batlantirdi va unga shimoliy iqtisodiyot bilan raqobatlashishga imkon berdi. Janubga joriy qilingan takomillashtirilgan qishloq xo'jaligi texnikalari ishlab chiqarishni ko'paytirdi va Tszin hukmdorlari qonunlarni qo'llaganligi sababli bozor iqtisodiyoti saqlanib qoldi. Janubiy iqtisodiyotning yaxshilanishi, keyinchalik Liu Yuning Sichuan va Xitoy yuragining aksariyat qismini qutqarish bo'yicha ekspeditsiyalarini moliyalashtirganida ko'rish mumkin. barbar shimoliy shtatlar.[95]

Janubiy va Shimoliy sulolalar (420–581)

A standing Buddha: a yellow statue made from limestone, with its hands in prayer and holding a lotus
A ohaktosh haykali Bodhisattva, dan Shimoliy Qi sulola, 570Idoralar, hozirgi zamonda ishlab chiqarilgan Xenan viloyat.

The Janubiy va Shimoliy sulolalar, doimiy urushga qaramay, asosan Xu Xu qo'zg'olonidan tiklandi. Eramizning dastlabki qismida Xitoyning aksariyat qismi mahalliy Lyu Song sulolasi tomonidan birlashdi, uning shimoliy chegarasi Sariq daryosigacha cho'zildi. Liu Song asoschisi va generali, Liu Yu, Xu Xu Shimoliy Vey Sianbei davlatini hisobga olmaganda, 4-asrda Xu Xu asos solgan davlatlarning ko'pini bosib olib, Xitoyning yuragining katta qismini qaytarib oldi. O'g'li boshchiligida Xitoy Yuanjia davrida qisqa muddatli farovonlik davrini guvohi bo'ldi. Biroq, keyinchalik Sianbey istilosi yana bir bor Xitoy sulolalarini janubdagi janubga qamab qo'ydi Xuay daryosi.[96] Bundan buyon Xitoy Shimoliy va Janubiy sulolalarga bo'linib, ular alohida rivojlanib bordi; shimol yangi teng maydonli tizim ostida gullab-yashnaydi, janubiy iqtisodiyot Vey va Tszin kabi rivojlanib boraverdi. 589 yilda Sui sulolasi Shimoliy Xitoyda mahalliy boshqaruvni tikladi va mamlakatni birlashtirdi.

Janubiy sulolalar

Lyu Yu va uning o'g'li tomonidan ochilgan Yuanjia davri, Ven Ti, davom etgan urushga qaramay, gullab-yashnagan hukmronlik va iqtisodiy o'sish davri edi. Imperator Ven Ti tejamkor ma'muriyati va xalq farovonligi haqida qayg'urishi bilan tanilgan. Garchi unga otasining jangovar kuchi etishmasa-da, u mukammal iqtisodiy menejer edi. U dehqonlar uchun soliqlar va yig'imlarni kamaytirdi va ularni otasi tomonidan qaytarib olingan hududlarga joylashishga undadi. U boy er egalarining hokimiyatini pasaytirdi va soliq solinadigan aholini ko'paytirdi. Shuningdek, u davlat xizmatchilarining faoliyatini ko'rib chiqish tizimini joriy etdi. Uning siyosati natijasida Xitoy farovonlik va iqtisodiy tiklanish davrini boshdan kechirdi.[97]

Yuanjia davrida xitoyliklar po'lat ishlab chiqarishning qo'shma termoyadroviy jarayonini ishlab chiqdilar, bu quyma temirni eritish va temir birgalikda temir ishlab chiqarish, Xitoy temirining sifati va ishlab chiqarish hajmini oshirish.[iqtibos kerak ]

Ven Ti hukmronligining oxiriga kelib, Sianbei davlati Shimoliy Vey kuchaytira boshladi va Ven Tining uni yo'q qilishga urinishini qat'iyan mag'lub etdi. Ushbu g'alabadan keyin Vey shimoliy viloyatlarga takroriy hujumlarni boshladi va nihoyat ularni 468 yilda qo'lga kiritdi.[96]

Xitoyning janubiy iqtisodiy farovonligi Liu Song qulaganidan keyin ham davom etdi va muvaffaqiyat qozongan davrda eng katta bo'ldi Liang sulolasi qisqa vaqt ichida general qo'mondonligi ostida 7000 qo'shin bilan Shimolni qaytarib oldi Chen Tszinji. Liang imperatori, Vu Ti, Buddist monastirlariga janubda mavjud bo'lgan boylik miqdorini ko'rsatib, 400 million tanga miqdorida grant berdi. Uning hukmronligi davrida shahar Nankin aholisi 1,4 milliongacha bo'lgan bo'lib, Xan davridan oshib ketgan Luoyang.[98] Afsuski, ishdan bo'shatilgandan so'ng, Janubiy sulolalar iqtisodiyoti pasayib ketdi Nankin barbar general Xou Jin tomonidan.[99]

Shimoliy sulolalar

Sianbei Shimoliy Xitoyni bosib olganidan so'ng, Shimoliy Vey davrida iqtisodiy tiklanishni boshdan kechirdi, bu Yuanjiyaning gullab-yashnagan davridan ham kattaroq edi. Bu asosan hukmronlik ostida bo'lgan Shimoliy Vey imperatori Xiaoven Shimoliy Veyni yanada gunoh qilishga qaratilgan bir qancha islohotlarni amalga oshirgan, shu qatorda Sianbei tili va urf-odatlarini taqiqlash va Xitoy qonunlari, tili va familiyalarini targ'ib qilish. Yangi qishloq xo'jaligi tizimi joriy etildi; teng maydonli tizimda davlat dehqon mehnatkashlariga erni ijarachi vafotidan keyin qaytarib olib, umrbod ijaraga oldi. Peasants also received smaller, private plots that could be inherited. Cattle and farm tools were also rented or sold to peasants.

The state also introduced the Fubing system, where soldiers would farm as well as undergoing military training. This military system was used until the Tang dynasty, and empowered Han Chinese, who comprised the majority of the army. In addition, Xiaowen strengthened the state's control over the provinces by appointing local officials rather than relying on local landowners, and paying officials with regular salaries. The capital was moved to Luoyang, in the centre of the Shimoliy Xitoy tekisligi, which revitalised the city and the surrounding provinces.[100] Xiaowen's reforms were very successful and lead to prosperity for north China. Under Emperor Xiaowen, the taxable population was an estimated 30 million, which surpassed that under the Jin.[100]

After Xiaowen's rule, Northern Wei's economy began to deteriorate, and famines and droughts undermined Wei rule. From 523 onwards, conservative Xianbei noblemen dominated the north and reversed much of Xiaowen's reforms, setting up their own regimes and warring against each other. It was not until 577 that North China was again reunited by Shimoliy Chjou, which was soon usurped by Han Chinese Yang Jian, who restored native rule over North China.[101]

Sui dynasty (581–618)

The Sui sulolasi was established over the Shimoliy Chjou, whose throne was usurped by Yang Szyan in 581. Yang Jian quickly enacted a series of policies to restore China's economy. His reunification of China marked the creation of what some historians call the 'Second Chinese Empire', spanning the Sui, T'ang and Shimoliy qo'shiq sulolalar. Despite its brevity, the Sui reunified China, and its laws and administration formed the basis of the later Tang, Song and Ming dynasties. Sui dynasty China had a population of about 45 million at its peak.[102]

One of Yang Jian (or Sui Wen Ti)'s first priorities was the reunification of China. Chen, which ruled the south, was weak compared to Sui and its ruler was incompetent and pleasure-loving. South China also had a smaller population than the north. After eight years of preparation, Sui armies marched on and defeated Chen in 589, reunifying China and prompting a recovery in the Chinese economy.[103] The registered population increased by fifty percent from 30 to 46 million in twenty years.[104]To encourage economic growth, the Sui government issued a new currency to replace those issued by its predecessors, Northern Zhou and Chen.[105] They also encouraged foreign merchants to travel to China and import goods, and built numerous hotels to house them.[106]

The Sui continued to use the equal-field system introduced by Northern Wei. Every able-bodied male received 40 mou of freehold land and a lifetime lease of 80 mou of land, which was returned to the state when the recipient died. Even women could received a lifetime lease of 40 mou of land which was returned to the state upon her death. The Sui government charged three "Shi" of grain each year. Peasants were required to perform 20 days of labour for the state per year, but those over 50 could instead pay a small fee.[107]

In 604, Wen Ti was assassinated by his son Yang Guang, who became Yang Ti of Sui. Yang Ti was an ambitious ruler who immediately undertook many projects, including the building of the Grand Canal and the reconstruction of the Great Wall. Thousands of forced labourers died while building the projects, and eventually women were required to labour in the absence of men. Sui Yang Ti also launched a series of unsuccessful campaigns against Goguryeo. These campaigns negatively impacted the image of the dynasty, while his policies drove the people to revolt. Agrarian uprisings and raids by the Gokturks keng tarqalgan bo'lib qoldi. In 618, Yang Ti was assassinated and the Sui dynasty ended.[108]

Tang dynasty (618–907)

A glazed figurine of a red camel, which is being ridden by a bearded merchant in green clothing
A Tang-era Chinese sancai - sirlangan Baqtriya tuya ridden by a bearded merchant from Fors; camels were the key hayvonlar to'plami da ishlatilgan Ipak yo'li savdo.

The Tang sulolasi was another golden age, beginning in the ruins of the Sui. By 630, the Tang had conquered the powerful Gokturk Khagnate, preventing threats to China's borders for more than a century. A series of strong and efficient rulers, beginning with the founder and including a woman, expanded the Tang Empire to the point that it rivalled the later Yuan, Ming and Qing. The Tang was a period of rapid economic growth and prosperity, seeing the beginnings of yog'och bloklarini bosib chiqarish. Tang rulers issued large amounts of currency to facilitate trade and distributed land under the equal-field system. The population recovered to and then surpassed Han levels, reaching an estimated 80 million.[iqtibos kerak ] Although the state weakened after the disastrous Shi isyoni, and withdrew from managing the economy in the 9th century, this withdrawal encouraged economic growth and helped China's economy to develop into the mercantile economy of the Song and Ming Dynasties.[102]

Before the An Shi Rebellion

Tang imperatori Taizong, the second ruler of the dynasty, is regarded as one of the greatest rulers in Chinese history. Under his rule, China progressed rapidly from the ruins of a civil war to a prosperous and powerful nation. His reign is called the Zhenkuan era. Taizong reduced conscript labour requirements and lowered taxes; in addition, he was careful to avoid undertaking projects that might deplete the treasury and exhaust the strength of the population. Under his reign, a legal code called the Code of Tang was introduced, moderating the laws of the Sui.[109]

During Taizong's reign and until the An Shi Rebellion, the Chinese Empire went through a relatively peaceful period of economic development. Taizong and his son's conquest of the Gokturk, Xueyantue, Gorguryeo and other enemy empires ensured relative peace for China. Control over the western provinces of China reopened the Silk Road, allowing trade between China and the regions to its west to flourish. Tang armies repeatedly intervened in the western regions to preserve this state of peace and prosperity.[110]

The equal-field system did not allow large land transactions and thus during the early Tang estates remained small. The Tang government managed the economy through the bureaucratic regulation of markets, limiting the times where they could exchange goods, setting standards for product quality, and regulating prices of produce.[111]

During the Tang, the taxation system was based on the equal-field system, which equalised wealth among the farmers. The tax burden of peasants was based on population per household, rather than the value of property. The standard tax amounted to 2 tan (about 100 litres) of grain, as well as 2 Zhang (around 3 1/3 meters) and 5 Chi (about 1/3 of a meter) of cloth. The peasant was eligible for 20 days' conscripted labour; if he defaulted he was obliged to pay 3 Chi of cloth per day missed.[112] Assuming each farmer had 30 mou of land which produced 1 tan of grain a year, the tax rate amounted to 25% of the farmer's income.[113] Commercial taxes were lighter, at 3.3% of income.

The Tang government operated a huge handicraft industry, separate from the private handicraft industry that served the majority of the population. The public handicraft industry provided the Tang government, army and nobility with various products. The government's handicraft industries retarded the growth of the private sector which did not develop rapidly until after the Anshi Rebellion, when the Tang government's interference in the economy (and the size of its government handicraft industries) drastically decreased.[114] Despite this, a large number of households worked in private industry; scholars have estimated that 10% of Tang China's population lived in cities.[113]

The height of Tang prosperity came during the Kaiyuan Era of Tang imperatori Xuanzong, who expanded Tang influence westward to the Orol dengizi.[115] Emperor Xuan was a capable administrator, and his Kaiyuan Era is often compared with the earlier Zhenkuan era in efficiency of administration. After this era, the Tang dynasty went into decline.

After the An Shi Rebellion

One plump woman wears a flower and chases a bird while another stands holding an umbrella.
Beauties Wearing Flowers, tomonidan Chjou Fang, 8th century

Emperor Xuanzong's reign ended with the Arab victory at Talas va Shi isyoni, the first war inside China in over 120 years, led by a So'g'diycha nomli general An Lushan who used a large number of foreign troops.[116] The Tang economy was devastated as the northern regions, the mainstay of economic activity, were destroyed. The cities of Luoyang and Chang'an were reduced to ruins. After the war, the Tang central government never recovered its former power, and local generals became independent of Tang rule. These generals wielded enormous power, passed on their titles by heredity, collected taxes, and raised their own armies.[116] Although most of these jiedushi were quelled by the early 9th century, the jiedushi of Hebei, many of them former officers of An Lushan, retained their independence.

The weakened Tang government was forced to abolish many of its regulations and interventions after the rebellion; this unintentionally stimulated trade and commerce in Tang China, which reached an apogee in the early 9th century.[117] The economic centre of China shifted southwards because the north had been devastated.[118]

The equal-field system, which had formed the basis of agriculture for the past two and a half centuries, began to collapse after the An Shi Rebellion. The equal-field system had relied on the state having large amounts of land, but state landholdings had decreased as they were privatised or granted to peasants. Landowners perpetually enlarging their estates exacerbated the collapse. The Fubing system, in which soldiers served the army and farmed on equal-field land was abolished and replaced with the Mubing system, which relied on a volunteer and standing army. In 780, the Tang government discontinued the equal field system and reorganised the tax system, collecting taxes based on property value twice a year, in spring and autumn.[119]

Woodblock printing began to develop during the 8th and 9th centuries. This grew out of the huge paper industry that had emerged since the Han. Woodblock printing allowed the rapid production of many books, and increased the speed at which knowledge spread. The first book to be printed in this manner, with a production date, was the Jin Gang Jin, a Buddhist text printed in 868,[118] but the hand-copying of manuscripts still remained much more important for centuries to come.[120] During the later years of the Tang dynasty, overseas trade also began with East Africa, India, and the Middle East.[iqtibos kerak ]

Although the economy recovered during the 9th century, the central government was weakened. The most pressing issue was the government's salt monopoly, which raised revenue after the equal-field system collapsed and the government could no longer collect land tax effectively. After the An Shi Rebellion, the Tang government monopolised salt to raise revenue; it soon accounted for over half the central government's revenues. During the reign of emperors Shi and Yi, private salt traders were executed, and the price of salt was so high that many people could not afford it. Eventually, private salt traders allied and rebelled against the Tang army.[121] This rebellion, known as the Huang Chao Rebellion,[122] lasted ten years and destroyed the countryside from Guangzhou to Chang'an.[123] Following the rebellion, two generals, the Shatuo Li Keqiang and the former rebel Chju Ven, dominated the Tang court.[123] Civil war broke out again in the early 10th century, ending with Zhu Wen's victory.[123] Following his victory, Zhu Wen forced the Tang emperor to abdicate, and the Tang empire disintegrated into a group of states known as the Five Dynasties and Ten Kingdoms.[123]

Five Dynasties and Ten Kingdoms period (907–960)

The Besh sulola va o'n qirollik was a period of warfare and disruption. After 907, the Tang government effectively disintegrated into several small states in the south, while the north saw a series of short-lived dynasties and barbarian invasions. A key event of the era was the conquest of North China by the Shatuo Turks. During their rule, the Shatuo gave the vital Sixteen Prefectures area, containing the natural geographical defences of North China and the eastern section of the Great Wall, to the Kidan, another barbarian people. This effectively left Northern China defenceless against incursions from the north, a major factor in the later fall of the Song dynasty. The Shatuo and Khitan invasions severely disrupted economic activity in the north and displaced economic activity southwards, and native Chinese rule was not restored until the Keyinchalik Chjou dynasty, the Song's precursor.[124]

The southern provinces remained relatively unaffected by the collapse. The Five Dynasties and Ten Kingdoms period was largely one of continued prosperity in these regions.[125]

Kech imperatorlik davri

Numerous coins with square holes and with Chinese characters inscribed
Chinese coins from the Tang to the Qing dynasties

In 960, Zhao Kuangyin led a coup which established the sixth dynasty in fifty years. The Qo'shiqlar sulolasi saw a steep economic rise of China.[126] The Late Imperial Era, encouraged by technological advancement, saw the beginnings of large-scale enterprise, waged labour and the issuing of qog'oz pul. The economy underwent large increases in manufacturing output. Overseas trade flourished under the Min sulolasi. Investment, capital, and commerce were liberalised as technology advanced and the central state weakened. Government manufacturing industries were privatised. The emergence of rural and urban markets, where production was geared towards consumption, was a key development in this era. China's growing wealth in this era lead to the loss of martial vigour; the era involved two periods of native rule, each followed by periods of alien rule. By the end of the isolationist Manchu Tsing sulolasi (1664–1911), China's development slowed, falling behind that of the west.

The food production grew thanks to more lands being cultivated and to the increasing yields. The production of iron and salt and other commodities also grew in this period. According to the GDP estimates by Broadberry et al., the per capita GPD was stable during the Song and Ming dynasties before going down during the Qing dynasty when the population increase outstripped the GDP growth. Thus Song China was the richest country in the world by GPD per capita at the turn of the millennium, by the 14th century parts of Europe caught up with it and the significant gap between China and Europe appeared by the middle of 18th century.[127]

Song dynasty (960–1279)

In 960, the Later Zhou general Zhao Kuanyi overthrew his imperial master and established the Song dynasty, the sixth in fifty-three years. Nineteen years later, he had reunified most of China. This was one of the most prosperous periods in Chinese history. Unlike its predecessors, the monarchy and aristocracy weakened under the Song, allowing a class of non-aristocratic gentry to gain power. The central government withdrew from managing the economy (except during Wang Anshi's chancellorship and the Southern Song), provoking drastic economic changes. Technological advances encouraged growth; three of the so-called Four Great Inventions: porox, yog'och bloklarini bosib chiqarish, va kompas, were invented or perfected during this era. The population rose to more than 100 million during the Song period. However, the Song eventually became the first unified Chinese dynasty to be completely conquered by invaders.[128]

Song industry

During the 11th century, China developed sophisticated technologies to extract and use coal for energy, leading to soaring iron production.[129] Iron production rose fivefold from 800 to 1078, to about 125,000 English tons (114,000 metric tons), not counting unregistered iron production.[130][131] Initially, the government restricted the iron industry, but the restrictions on private smelting was lifted after the prominent official Bao Tsintian 's (999-1062) petition to the government[132] Production of other metals also soared; officially registered Song production of silver, bronze, tin, and lead increased to 3, 23, 54, and 49 times that of Tang levels.[133] Officially registered Salt production also rose at least 57%.[134]

The government regulated several other industries. Sulphur, an ingredient in gunpowder – a crucial new weapon introduced during the Tang – became a growth industry, and in 1076 was placed under government control.[135] Yilda Sichuan province, revenue from the Song government's monopoly on tea was used to purchase horses for the Song's cavalry forces.[136] Kantsler Vang Anshi instated monopolies in several industries, sparking controversy.[137]

In order to supply the boom in the iron and other industries, the output of mines increased massively. Yaqin Byansjin, the Song capital, according to one estimate over one million households were using coal for heating, an indication of the magnitude of coal use.[138] Light industries also began to prosper during the Song, including porcelain – which replaced pottery – shipbuilding and textiles.[138] Compared with the Tang, textile production increased 55%.[139] The historian Xie Qia estimates that over 100,000 households were working in textile production by Song times, an indicator of the magnitude of the Song textile industry.[113] The urbanisation rate of the Song increased to 12%, compared with 10% during the Tang.[113]

Song agriculture

Agriculture advanced greatly under the Song. The Song government started a series of irrigation projects that increased cultivatable land, and encouraged peasants to cultivate more land. The total area of cultivated land was greatly increased to 720 million mou, a figure unsurpassed by later dynasties.[140] A variety of crops were cultivated, unlike the monokulturalar of previous dynasties. Specialised crops like oranges and sugar cane were regularly planted alongside rice.[141] Unlike the earlier self-sufficient peasantry of the Han and Tang eras, rural families produced a surplus which could be sold. The income allowed families to afford not only food, but charcoal, tea, oil, and wine. Many Song peasants supplemented their incomes with handicraft work.[142][143]

New tools, like the Suv g'ildiragi, greatly enhanced productivity. Although most peasants in China were still primarily rice farmers, some farmers specialised in certain crops. For example, Luoyang was known for its flower cultivation; flower prices reached such exorbitant prices that one bulb reached the price of 10,000 coins.[144] An important new crop introduced during the Song was Champa rice, a new breed which had superior yields to earlier forms of rice and greatly increased rice production.[145] The practice of multiple cropping, which increased yields by allowed farmers to harvest rice twice a year, was a key innovation of the Song era.[145] Per-mou agricultural output doubled for South China, while increasing only slightly in the north. Scholars offer "conservative estimates" which suggest that agricultural yields rose at least 20% during the Song.[146] Other scholars note that although taxable land rose only 5% during the Song, the actual amount of grain revenues taken in increased by 46%.[146]

Agricultural organisation also changed. Unlike the Han and Tang, in which agriculture was dominated by self-sufficient farmers, or the pre-Warring States period and era of division (period between Han and Tang), which was dominated by aristocratic landowners, during the Song agriculture was dominated by non-aristocratic landowners. The majority of farmers no longer owned their land; they became tenants of these landowners, who developed the rural economy through investment. This system of agriculture was to continue until the establishment of the People's Republic of China under Mao.[147]

Song commerce

Chinese ships on a busy and inhabited shoreline
Chinese boats dan Chjan Zeduan rasm (1085–1145) Qingming festivali paytida daryo bo'yida; Chinese ships of the Song period featured korpuslar bilan suv o'tkazmaydigan bo'limlar o'rniga a keel with ribs

During the Song dynasty, the merchant class became more sophisticated, well-respected, and organised. The accumulated wealth of the merchant class often rivalled that of the olim-amaldorlar who administered the affairs of government. For their organisational skills, Ebrey, Walthall, and Palais state that Song dynasty merchants:

... set up partnerships and joint stock companies, with a separation of owners (aktsiyadorlar ) and managers. In large cities, merchants were organised into gildiyalar according to the type of product sold; they periodically set prices and arranged sales from wholesalers to shop owners. When the government requisitioned goods or assessed taxes, it dealt with the guild heads.[148]

Unfortunately, like their counterparts in Europe, these guilds restricted economic growth through collaboration with government to restrict competition.[149]

Large privately owned korxonalar dominated the market system of urban Song China. There was a large qora bozor, which grew after the Jur'chen conquest of North China in 1127. Around 1160, black marketeers smuggled some 70 to 80 thousand qoramol.[150]

There were many successful small pechlar va sopol idishlar shops owned by local families, along with oil presses, vino -making shops, and paper-making businesses.[151] The "... karvonsaroy keeper, the petty diviner, the drug seller, the cloth trader," also experienced increased economic success.[152]

Song abolition of trade restrictions greatly aided the economy. Commerce increased in frequency and could be conducted anywhere, in contrast to earlier periods where trade was restricted to the 'Fang' and 'Shi' areas. In all the major cities of the Song dynasty, many shops opened. Often, shops selling the same product were concentrated into one urban area. For example, all the rice shops would occupy one street, and all the fish shops another.[153] Unlike the later Ming dynasty, most businesses during the Song dynasty were producers and retailers, selling the products they produced, thus creating a mixture of handicraft and commerce. Although the Song dynasty saw some large enterprises, the majority of enterprises were small.[154]

Overseas commerce also prospered with the invention of the compass and the encouragement of Song rulers.[155] Developments in shipping and navigation technologies allowed trade and investment on a large scale. The Song-era Chinese could conduct large amounts of overseas trade, bringing some merchants great fortune.[156] Song-era commercial enterprises became very complex. The accumulated wealth of merchants often rivalled that of the scholar-officials who administered the affairs of government.

a paper banknote with Chinese characters and images inscribed
Jiaozhi, the world's first paper money. It was introduced during the Song dynasty

Song currency

The prosperous Song economy resulted in an increase in the minting of currency. By 1085, the output of copper currency reached 6 billion coins a year, compared to 5.86 billion in 1080. 327 million coins were minted annually in the Tang dynasty's prosperous Tianbao period of 742–755, and only 220 million coins minted annually from 118 Miloddan avvalgi 5 gaIdoralar during the Han dynasty.[157]

Paper receipts of deposit first appeared in the 10th century, but the first officially sponsored bills were introduced in Sichuan Province,[158] where the currency was metallic and extremely heavy. Although businesses began to issue private bills of exchange, by the mid-11th century the central government introduced its paper money, produced using yog'och bloklarini bosib chiqarish and backed by bronze coins. The Song government had also been amassing large amounts of paper tribute. Each year before 1101, the prefecture of Xinan (modern Xi-xian, Anhui) alone sent 1,500,000 sheets of paper in seven different varieties to the capital at Kaifeng.[159] In the Southern Song, standard currency bearing a marked face value, was used. However, a lack of standards caused face values to wildly fluctuate. A nationwide standard paper currency was not produced until 1274, two years before the Southern Song's fall.[160]

Song fiscal administration

The Song government instituted a taxation system on agriculture in which a property value tax was collected twice every year, amounting to roughly 10% of income.[113] However, the actual level was higher due to numerous surcharges. Commercial taxes were around 2%.[113] In an important change from Tang practices, however, the Song did not attempt to regulate prices and markets, with the exception of the time of Vang Anshi, though it also instituted an indirect monopoly in salt, in which merchants had to deliver grain to the state before being allowed to sell salt.[113][161]

In 1069, Wang Anshi, whose ideas were similar to the modern ijtimoiy davlat, kansler bo'ldi. Believing that the state must provide for the people, and pressed by the need for revenues to wage an irredentist war against the Si Sya va Liao, he initiated a series of reforms. These reforms included nationalising industries such as tea, salt and liquor, and adopting a policy of directly transporting goods in abundance in one region to another, which Wang believed would eliminate the need for merchants. Other policies included a rural credit program for peasants, the replacement of corvee labour with a tax, lending peasants military horses for use in peacetime, compulsory military training for civilians, and a "market exchange bureau" to set prices. These policies were extremely controversial, especially to Orthodox Confucians who favoured laissez faire, and were largely repealed after Wang Anshi's death, except during the reign of Emperor Huizong.[162]

A second, more serious attempt to intervene in the economy occurred in the late 13th century, when the Song dynasty suffered from fiscal problems while trying to defend themselves against Mongol invasions. The Song chancellor Jia Sidao attempted to solve the problem through land nationalisation, a policy that was heavily opposed and later withdrawn.[163]

Song collapse

The prosperity of the Song was interrupted by the invasion of Jur'chen Jin in 1127. After a successful alliance with the Jin in which the Song destroyed its old enemy the Khitan, the Jin attacked the Song and sacked its capital in Kaifeng.[164] The invasion preceded 15 years of constant warfare which ended when the Song court surrendered territory north of the Xuay daryosi in exchange for peace, despite victories by the Song general Yue Fey, who had almost defeated the Jur'chens.[165] The southern Chinese provinces became the center of commerce. Millions of Chinese fled Jur'chen rule to the South, which the Song dynasty still held.[166]

Due to the new military pressure of the Jur'chens, the Southern Song massively increased the tax burden to several times of that of the Northern Song. The Southern Song maintained an uneasy truce with the Jin until the rise of the Mongols, with whom Song allied to destroy the Jin in 1234.[167] Taking advantage of this, the Song army briefly recaptured their lost territory south of the Yellow River as the Mongols withdrew. However, a flood of the Yellow River, coupled with Mongol attacks, eventually forced the Song to withdraw.[168]

Seeking to conquer China, the Mo'g'ul imperiyasi launched a series of attacks on the Song.[169] By the 1270s, the Song economy had collapsed from the burden of taxes and inflation which the Song government used to finance its war against the Mongols.[170] In 1275, the Mongols defeated the Song army near Xiangyang and captured Xanchjou,[171] the Song capital, the following year. Song resistance ended at the Yaman jangi, in which the last Song emperor drowned with the remnants of his navy.[172] The destruction caused by the barbarian invasions in the later half of the Song represented a major setback in China's development.[173]

Yuan dynasty (1271–1368)

A set of waterwheels hooked with a rope to a blast furnace operating to produce iron
To'plam suv g'ildiraklari used to operate a yuqori o'choq producing iron, an illustration from the Nong Shu (農書) published by the official Vang Zhen 1313 yilda

The Mo'g'ul Yuan sulolasi was the first foreign dynasty to rule the whole of China. Eng kattasi sifatida xonlik in the Mongol Empire, the emperors of Yuan had nominal authority over the other three Mongol Empires. Ushbu davr Pax Mongolica stimulated trade. However, millions of Chinese died because of the Mongol conquest.[174] Under Mongol rule, approximately 65 million people were registered in 1290; in 1215, the dynasties of Jur'chen Jin and Song had registered populations of between 110 and 120 million.[175] In addition, the Mongol government later imposed high taxes and extensively nationalised major sectors of the economy, greatly damaging what was left of China's economic development.

In their conquest of China, particularly the north under Jur'chen Jin, the Mongols resorted to kuygan er policies, destroying entire provinces. Mongol forces carried out massacres in cities they captured, and one Xon proposed that all Chinese under Mongol rule be killed and their lands turned to pasture,[174] but was persuaded against this by his minister Yelu Chukay, who proposed that taxing the region's inhabitants was more advantageous than killing them.[176]

Xubilay Xon, after becoming ruler of China, extended the Katta kanal, connecting the Yellow and Yangtze rivers, to the capital, Pekin. This eased transportation between the south, now the hub of economic activity, and Beijing. This enhanced Beijing's status, it having formerly been a peripheral city, and was important to later regimes' decisions to have it remain the capital.[177]

The Yuan Government revolutionised the economy by introducing paper currency as the predominant circulating medium.[iqtibos kerak ] The founder of the Yuan dynasty, Kublai Khan, issued paper money known as Chao in his reign. Chinese paper money was guaranteed by the State and not by the private merchant or private banker. The concept of banknotes was not brought up in the world ever since until during the 13th century in Europe, with proper banknotes appearing in the 17th century. The original notes during the Yuan dynasty were restricted in area and duration as in the Song dynasty, but in the later course of the dynasty, facing massive shortages of specie to fund their ruling in China, began printing paper money without restrictions on duration. Chinese paper money was therefore guaranteed by the State and not by the private merchant or private banker.

Kublai and his fellow rulers encouraged trade between China and other Khanates of the Mongol Empire. During this era, trade between China and the Middle East increased, and many Arabs, Persians, and other foreigners entered China, some permanently immigrating. It was during this period that Marko Polo visited China.[178] Although Kublai Khan wished to identify with his Chinese subjects, Mongol rule was strict and foreign to the Chinese. Civil service examinations, the traditional way that Chinese elites entered the government, was ended, and most government positions were held by non-Chinese, especially the financial administration of the state.[179]

Over-spending by Kublai and his successor caused them to resort to high taxes and extensive state monopolization of major sectors of the economy to fund their extravagant spending and military campaigns, which became a major burden on the Chinese economy.[180] State monopolies were instituted in salt, iron, sugar, porcelain, tea, vinegar, alcohol and other industries. The most controversial of Kublai's policies, however, was opening the tombs of the Song emperors to gain treasure for the treasury,[181] and issuing large amounts of notes which caused giperinflyatsiya. These policies greatly conflicted with Confucian ideals of frugal government and light taxation.[182] As a result of Kublai's policies, and the discrimination of the Mongols towards the Chinese,[183] South China was beset by violent insurrections against Mongol rule. Many Chinese refused to serve or associate themselves with the Yuan administration, who they viewed as barbarian despots.[184]

During the 1340s, frequent famines, droughts, and plagues encouraged unrest among the Chinese. In 1351, a peasant rebel leader, who claimed he was the descendant of the Song Emperor Huizong, sought to restore the Song by driving out the Mongols. By 1360, much of South China was free of Mongol rule and had been divided into regional states, such as Zhu Yuanzhang's Ming, Zhang Shichen's Wu and Chen Yolian's Han. On the other hand, North China became divided between regional warlords who were only nominally loyal to the Yuan.[185] In 1368, after reunifying South China, the Ming dynasty advanced northward and captured Beijing, ending the Yuan.[186]

Ming dynasty (1368–1644)

Ning portreti Xongvu imperatori (r. 1368–1398)

Following the unrest in the late Yuan dynasty, the peasant Chju Yuanjang led a rebellion against Mongol rule.[187] U asos solgan Min sulolasi, whose reign is considered one of China's Golden Ages.[188] Private industries replaced those managed by the state. Vibrant foreign trade allowed contact to become established between East and West. Naqd ekinlar were more frequently grown, specialised industries were founded, and the economic growth caused by privatisation of state industries resulted in one of the most prosperous periods in Chinese history, exceeding that of the earlier Qo'shiqlar sulolasi.

The Ming was also a period of technological progress, though less so than the earlier Song.[189] It is estimated that Ming China had a population of approximately 150 million in 1600.[iqtibos kerak ]

Ming erta

Zhu Yuanzhang, also called the Xongvu imperatori, was born of a peasant family and was sympathetic towards peasants. Zhu enacted a series of policies designed to favour agriculture at the expense of other industries. The state gave aid to farmers, providing land and agricultural equipment and revising the taxation system.[189] The state also repaired many long-neglected canals and dikes that had aided agriculture. In addition, the Ming dynasty reinstated the examination system.[190]

Hongwu's successor and grandson, the Tszianven imperatori, was overthrown by his uncle, Zhu Di, deb nomlangan Yongle imperatori, in a bloody civil war that lasted three years. Zhu Di was more liberally-minded than his father and he repealed many of the controls on gentry and merchants.[191] Thus, his reign is sometimes regarded as a 'second founding' of the Ming dynasty. The ekspeditsiyalar of his eunuch Chjen Xe created new trade routes. Under Yongle's rule, Ming armies enjoyed continued victories against the Mongols, who were forced to acknowledge him as their ruler.[192] He also moved the capital to Beijing.[193] By Yongle's reign, China had recovered the territories of Eastern Xinjiang, Manchuria, Tibet, and those lost during the Five Dynasties and Ten Kingdoms Era.

Ming fiscal administration

The Ming government has been described as "... one of the greatest achievements of Chinese civilization".[194] Although it began as a despotic regime, the Ming government evolved into a system of power-sharing between the emperor and the civil service.

The Ming government collected far less revenue than the Song dynasty. Regional tax quotas set up by the Ming emperor Tai-Tzu would be collected, though in practice Ming revenues were markedly lower than the quotas declared. The gentry class won concessions from the government and resisted tax increases. Throughout the Ming dynasty, the state was constantly underfunded.[195] Unlike earlier dynasties such as the Tang and Song, and later dynasties such as the Qing, the Ming did not regulate the economy, but had a laissez-faire policy similar to that of the Han dynasty.[196] The Cambridge history of China volume on the Ming Dynasty stated that:

Ming government allowed those Chinese people who could attain more than mere subsistence to employ their resources mostly for the uses freely chosen by them, for it was a government that, by comparison with others throughout the world then and later, taxed the people at very low levels and left most of the wealth generated by its productive people in theregions where that wealth was produced.[197]

Key Ming taxes included the land tax (21 million taels),[198] the service levy (direct requisitioning of labour services and goods from civilians, valued at about 10 million taels), and the revenue from the Ming salt monopoly (2 million taels).[199] Other miscellaneous sources of revenue included the inland customs duty (343,729 taels), sale of rank (500,000 taels), licensing fees for monks (200,000 taels), and fines (300,000 taels) and others, which all added up to about 4 million taels. The overall Ming tax rate was very low, at around 3 to 4%.[200] However, by the end of the dynasty, this situation had changed dramatically. Chjan Juzheng instituted the one whip reform, in which the arbitrary service levy was merged into the land tax. The Ming government's salt monopoly was undermined by private sellers, and had collapsed completely by the 15th century; government officials estimated that three-quarters of salt produced was being sold privately.[201]

Ming commerce and currency

A porcelain jar with a red handle on top along with yellow dragons and clouds inscribed on a red background
A chinni jar from the reign of the Jiajing imperatori (r. 1521–1567); Xitoy eksport chinni in the late Ming targeted foreign markets such as those in Europe.[202]

Zhu Yuanzhang had promoted foreign trade as a source of revenue while he was a rebel, but sharply curtailed this with a series of dengiz taqiqlari (haijin) once in power.[203] These proclaimed the death penalty for private foreign traders and exile for their family and relatives in 1371;[204] the foreign ports of Guanchjou, Quanzhou va Ningbo were closed in 1384.[205]After the ´voyages to the western oceans ´ between 1405 and 1433, which had shown China to be technically ahead shipbuilding, a restrictive closed-door policy towards long-distance trade was adopted.[206]Legal trade was restricted to tribute delegations sent to or by official representatives of foreign governments,[207] although this took on an epic scale under the Yongle imperatori bilan Chjen Xe "s xazina sayohatlari ga Janubi-sharqiy Osiyo, India, and eastern Afrika.[196] The policies exacerbated "Japanese" piracy qirg'oqlari bo'ylab, ko'plab xitoylik savdogarlar o'zlarining saflariga noqonuniy savdo tarmog'iga qo'shilishganligi sababli, Ming qisqartirolmadi. Dengiz taqiqlari nihoyat 1567 yilda tugatildi,[196] savdo bilan faqat taxt bilan urushayotgan davlatlarga taqiq qo'yilgan. Nidxem taqiqning oxiri va sulola oxiri (1567–1644) o'rtasidagi savdoni taxminan 300 mln poyabzal.

Ga qo'shimcha sifatida kichik metall tangalar, Ming chiqarilgan Fiat qog'oz valyuta hukmronlik boshidan 1450 yilgacha standart valyuta sifatida, shu vaqtga qadar uning salaflari - azob chekayotgan edi giperinflyatsiya va keng tarqalgan qalbakilashtirish. (1425 yilda Ming yozuvlari Hongwu imperatori davrida asl qiymatining 0,014% atrofida sotilgan.)[208] Pul ehtiyojlari dastlab qondirildi quyma kumush bilan savdo qilish sycee, ammo 15-asr o'rtalarida kumush etishmovchiligi pulning keskin qisqarishiga olib keldi va ko'p savdoni ayirboshlash yo'li bilan olib borishga majbur qildi.[209] Xitoy Evropa yoki Yaponiya tovarlariga emas, kumushlariga juda qiziqqan edi Ivami Ginzan va Potosi cheklash uchun juda foydali va muhim edi.[210][211] Yaponiya va Ispaniya kumushining kirib kelishi Xitoy iqtisodiyotini monetizatsiya qildi va Ispaniya dollari umumiy muomala vositasiga aylandi.[212]

Kechki Ming iqtisodiyotining hajmi taxminlarga bog'liq bo'lib, Tvithet uni dunyodagi eng katta va eng boy millat deb da'vo qilmoqda.[195] va Maddison uni taxmin qilish jon boshiga YaIM o'rtacha Osiyo va Evropadan pastroq.[213]

Ming sanoati

1400 yildan keyin Ming Xitoyning iqtisodiy tiklanishi yuqori iqtisodiy o'sishga va ko'mir va temir kabi og'ir sanoatning tiklanishiga olib keldi. Sanoat ishlab chiqarilishi Song'dan oshib yangi balandliklarga erishdi. Songdan farqli o'laroq, yangi sanoat markazlari Shimoliy Xitoyda emas, balki janubda joylashgan bo'lib, ko'mirga kirish imkoniga ega emas edi. Katta farq.[214] Temir ishlab chiqarish uch baravarga oshdi va 300 ming tonnadan oshdi.[215] Keyingi yangiliklar sanoat salohiyatini Song darajasidan yuqori darajaga ko'tarishga yordam berdi.[129] Ming davridagi ko'plab yangiliklar qayd etilgan Tiangong Kayvu, 1637 yilda tuzilgan entsiklopediya.

Ming qishloq xo'jaligi

Ming davrida ba'zi qishloq joylar faqat naqd paxta hosilini etishtirish uchun ajratilgan edi. Qishloq xo'jaligi asboblari va aravalari, ba'zilari suv bilan ishlaydigan, qishloq xo'jaligining asosini tashkil etadigan qishloq xo'jaligining ortiqcha mahsulotlarini ishlab chiqarishga imkon berdi. Boshqa ekinlar qatorida sholi ham keng miqyosda etishtirildi.[216] Aholining ko'payishi va unumdor erlarning kamayishi dehqonlar pul topish uchun naqd ekinlarni etishtirishni talab qildi.[217] Qurilgan, boshqariladigan mulklar sezilarli darajada o'sdi; 1379 yilda atigi 14241 xonadonda 700 mou bo'lgan bo'lsa, Ming oxiriga kelib ba'zi yirik er egalari 70 ming moudan oshgan.[218] Tijoratlashtirishning kuchayishi Min sulolasi davrida unumdorlikda katta yutuqlarga olib keldi va aholi sonining ko'payishiga imkon berdi.[219]

Qishloq joylarida uchta asosiy turga ega bo'lgan ko'plab bozorlar tashkil etildi. Eng oddiy bozorlarda tovarlar almashinadigan yoki barter qildi.[217] "Shahar-qishloq" bozorlarida qishloq mollari shahar aholisiga sotilgan; shaharlarda yashovchi uy egalari shaharlarda almashinuvni osonlashtirish uchun qishloq mulklaridan olinadigan daromadlardan foydalanganlar. Savdogarlar qishloq mollarini katta miqdorda sotib olib, ushbu bozorlarda sotishgan.[217] Song sulolasi davrida rivojlangan "milliy bozor" Ming davrida muhimroq bo'ldi. Ushbu turdagi bozorda savdogarlar va barterlardan tashqari, to'g'ridan-to'g'ri bozor uchun ishlab chiqarilgan mahsulotlar ishtirok etdi. Ko'p Ming dehqonlari endi ishonishmadi yordamchi dehqonchilik; bozor uchun mahsulot ishlab chiqarishdi, uni foyda olish uchun sotishdi.[217] Kembrij tarixi Ming haqida shunday deydi:

"Ming jamiyatining kengayib borayotgan kommunikatsiyalar doirasida tijoratlashtirilishi ushbu sulola tarixining ajralib turadigan jihati sifatida qaralishi mumkin. Tovar ishlab chiqarish va muomalada Ming Xitoy tarixida ham, bozor uchun qaysi tovarlar ishlab chiqarilayotganligi va tijorat ayirboshlashni boshqaradigan iqtisodiy munosabatlar tabiati.[220]"

A building with many richly dressed women inside in the background with two men standing
Xon saroyida bahor tongi, tomonidan Qiu Ying (1494-1552); haddan ziyod hashamat va tanazzul ulkan davlat tomonidan qo'zg'atilgan so'nggi Ming davri belgilaridir quyma kiruvchi kumush va kumush bilan bog'liq shaxsiy bitimlar.

Ming qulashi

Ming sulolasi oxirida Kichik muzlik davri shimoliy viloyatlarda Xitoy qishloq xo'jaligini jiddiy ravishda qisqartirdi. 1626 yildan boshlab Shimoliy Xitoyda ocharchilik, qurg'oqchilik va boshqa ofatlar boshlanib, dehqonlar qo'zg'olonlarini keltirib chiqardi. Ming hukumatining soliqlarni yig'a olmasligi natijasida qo'shinlar tez-tez maosh olmaydilar. Ko'plab qo'shinlar isyonchilarga qo'shilib, vaziyatni yomonlashtirdi. 1644 yilda isyonchilar qo'l ostida Li Zicheng shimolda Ming hukmronligini tugatib, Pekinni oldi.[221] Ming taxtiga sodiq rejimlar (birgalikda Janubiy Ming ) 1662 yilgacha janubiy Xitoyda hukmronlik qilishni davom ettirdi.[221] Yaqinda tarixchilar kumush etishmovchiligi Ming sulolasining qulashiga sabab bo'lgan degan nazariyaning haqiqiyligi haqida bahslashmoqdalar.[222]</ref>[223]

Tsing sulolasi (1644–1912)

Xitoyning so'nggi imperatorlik sulolasi Tsing sulolasi, tomonidan tashkil etilgan Jurxenlar, keyinchalik Manjurlar, Mingga bo'ysungan va ilgari asos solgan Jurchen Jin sulolasi.[224] 1616 yilda, ostida Nurhaci, manjurlar Minga hujum qildi. 1644 yilda Pekin ishdan bo'shatildi Li Zicheng isyonchi kuchlar va Chongjen imperatori shahar qulab tushganda o'z joniga qasd qildi. Shundan keyin Manchu Tsing sulolasi Ming sobiq sarkardasi bilan ittifoqchilik qildi Vu Sangui va Pekin ustidan nazoratni qo'lga kiritdi va Lining qisqa muddatli hayotini tezda ag'darib tashladi Shunlar sulolasi. Faqat 1683 yilgacha bir necha o'n yillardan so'ng Tsin butun Xitoyni o'z qo'liga oldi.[225] Asr oxiriga kelib Xitoy iqtisodiyoti avvalgi urushlar natijasida vujudga kelgan vayronagarchiliklardan va natijada tartibning buzilishidan qutuldi. 18-asrda Tsing iqtisodiyoti sezilarli darajada rivojlanib, bozorlar kengayishda davom etgan bo'lsa-da, Evropa davlatlari iqtisodiyoti bilan hamqadam bo'la olmadi. Sanoat inqilobi.[226]

Erta Qing

Garchi manjurlar tomonidan o'rnatilgan Tsin sulolasi tezda egallab olingan bo'lsa-da Pekin 1644 yilda Xitoyning boshqa qismlarida dushmanlik rejimlari hanuzgacha mavjud bo'lib, butun Xitoyni o'z nazorati ostiga olish uchun Tsinga bir necha o'n yillar kerak bo'ladi. Bu davrda, ayniqsa 1640 va 1650 yillarda odamlar ochlikdan va kasallikdan vafot etishdi, natijada aholi soni kamaydi. 1661 yilda Tsing hukumati xorijdagi Mingga sodiq kuchlarning hujumlariga duch kelib, siyosat olib bordi qirg'oq chizig'ini tozalash, bu sohil bo'yida yashovchi barcha odamlarga buyruq bergan Chjetszyan bilan chegaraga Vetnam 25 kilometr (16 milya) ichkariga o'tish uchun va u erda hech kim yashamasligi uchun qo'riqchilar qirg'oqda joylashgan. Shunday qilib, 1685 yilgacha bir necha kishi qirg'oq bo'yi va tashqi savdo bilan shug'ullangan. Ushbu o'n yilliklarda, garchi g'alla o'rim-yig'imi yaxshilangan bo'lsa-da, bozorda ozchilik qatnashgan, chunki iqtisodiyot qisqargan va mahalliy narxlar pastga tushgan. Iste'fodagi xitoylik olim va muvaffaqiyatsiz savdogar Tang Chen 1690 yillarning boshlarida o'z yozgan asarida o'tgan o'n yilliklarning bozor iqtisodiyotining yomon ahvolini tasvirlab berdi.[n 4]

Vaziyat tinchlik asta-sekin tiklangandan keyingina sezilarli darajada yaxshilandi. 1680-yillarga kelib Tsin imperiya ustidan nazoratni kuchaytirdi va qulay iqtisodiy o'zgarishlar tiklandi. Ushbu o'zgarishlar kech Ming kengayishiga o'xshaydi, ammo dastlabki Qing bozori mintaqalararo savdo-sotiqqa ko'proq ega edi, ko'proq chet el bozorlariga bog'liq edi va aholisi ko'proq edi. Ayni paytda bozor bilan odatiy va buyruqbozlik iqtisodiyoti o'rtasidagi munosabatlar o'zgardi.[228]

Kang-Qian yoshi

Two cranes near a pine tree. One is feeding on the ground while another rears its head high. Red flowers are also in the background
Qarag'ay, olxo'ri va turnalar, 1759 Idoralar, tomonidan Shen Quan (1682–1760). Osilib turmoq, ipakdagi siyoh va rang. The Saroy muzeyi, Pekin.

1683 yilga kelib janubdagi barcha Ming qirolliklarini tor-mor qilganlaridan so'ng Kansi imperatori knyazlik mulklari va kabi buzg'unchi choralarni bekor qildi qirg'oqni tozalash. U urushda vayron bo'lgan iqtisodiyotni tezda tikladi va tarixda katta farovonlik davrini boshladi. Uning vorislari davrida Tsin sulolasi Kang-Qian davrida eng yuqori cho'qqiga erishdi. Kansi imperatori va Qianlong imperatori.[229] Bu davr "Yuqori Qing" nomi bilan ham tanilgan, bu davrda Kansi va uning vorislari hududlarni boshqargan Shinjon va Tibet, zabt etdi Jungar xonligi[230] va bu hududlar ustidan Min sulolasiga qaraganda qattiqroq nazoratni amalga oshirdi. Bu Xitoy uchun katta xavfni olib tashladi va Shinjon va Mo'g'uliston hududlarini Xitoy iqtisodiyotiga qo'shib qo'ydi.

Tsing sulolasi davrida chet el oziq-ovqat ekinlari, kartoshka singari, 18-asrda keng miqyosda joriy qilingan.[231] Ushbu ekinlar, 18-asrdagi umumiy tinchlik bilan bir qatorda, Ming davrida taxminan 150-200 million kishidan Qing paytida 400 milliondan oshiqgacha bo'lgan aholi sonining keskin o'sishiga turtki berdi.[232] XVIII asr davomida bozorlar kech Ming davridagi kabi kengayishda davom etdi. Bozorda qatnashish uchun odamlarga ko'proq imtiyozlar berish uchun ular soliq yukini marhum Mingga nisbatan kamaytirdilar va o'rniga Korvi ishchilarni yollashda foydalaniladigan bosh solig'i bo'lgan tizim. Xitoy eksport qilishni davom ettirdi choy, ipak va ishlab chiqaradi, katta, qulay yaratadi savdo balansi G'arb bilan.[233]

Ming tendentsiyalaridan birini o'zgartirib, Tsin hukumati iqtisodiyotga katta aralashdi. Tuzga monopoliya tiklandi va davlat uchun eng katta daromad manbalaridan biriga aylandi. Qing mulozimlari g'alla foydasiga naqd ekinlarni etishtirishdan voz kechishga harakat qilishdi.[234] Boy savdogarlarning hokimiyatidan ehtiyot bo'lgan Qing hukmdorlari o'zlarining savdo litsenziyalarini cheklashdi va odatda kambag'al hududlardan tashqari ularga yangi konlarni ochish uchun ruxsat berishdan bosh tortdilar.[235] Savdo gildiyalari o'sib borayotgan Xitoyning barcha shaharlarida ko'payib bordi va ko'pincha katta ijtimoiy va hatto sotib olishdi siyosiy ta'sir. Rasmiy aloqalari bo'lgan boy savdogarlar ulkan boyliklarni qurdilar va homiylik qildilar adabiyot, teatr va san'at. Mato va hunarmandchilik ishlab chiqarish jadal rivojlandi.[233]

Mis Yaponiyadan olingan.[236][237][238][239][240][241] Mis Yunnandan ham kelgan.[242]

Qing Xalqaro savdo

Qing savdo siyosati keng edi izolyatsionist, bilan Qianlong imperatori ayniqsa buni e'lon qilish

Daoguang davr Peking stakan vaza. Rang Tsin sulolasi bayrog'idan keyin "Imperial Yellow" deb nomlangan.

Bizning erimiz shu qadar boy va obodki, biz hamma narsaga egamiz. Shuning uchun, mahsulotlarini almashtirishga hojat yo'q chet ellik barbarlar o'zimiz uchun.[243]

Tufayli Ming sodiqlari kabi Koxinga, regent Shahzoda Rui davom ettirdi xususiy tashqi savdoni taqiqlash 1647 yilda. Aslida, avvalgi Ming singari, Tsing imperiyasi tashqi savdoga bog'liq edi Yapon va Janubiy Amerika pul tizimiga asos solgan kumush va taqiq 1661 yilda kuzatilgan yanada qattiq tartibgacha samarali bo'lmadi[244] ko'tarilishidan keyin Kansi imperatori. Xitoy tili Guandun, Fujian, Chjetszyan, Tszansu va qismlari Shandun keyingi uch yil ichida qirg'oqdan majburan olib tashlangan Katta tozalash.[244] Kemalar vayron bo'ldi va tashqi savdo yana o'tib ketish bilan cheklandi Makao.[244] Taxtga yuqori darajadagi yodgorliklardan so'ng, evakuatsiya 1669 yildan keyin amalga oshirilmadi[245] va yo'q qilinganidan keyin Tungning kuni Tayvan, boshqa taqiqlar 1684 yilda bekor qilingan.[244] Bir yil o'tib, bojxona idoralari tashkil etildi Guanchjou, Xiamen, Ningbo, va Songjiang tashqi savdo bilan shug'ullanish uchun.[246] Juda katta emigratsiya ushbu siyosatda qatnashgan[247] - Ming da'vogarining mish-mishlari bilan birga Filippinlar - sabab bo'lgan Kansi imperatori bilan savdo qilishni taqiqlash Janubiy Xitoy dengizi va 1717 yilda muhojirlarga o'lim jazosi bilan qaytishni buyurish; o'n yil o'tgach, bu bekor qilindi, ammo xizmat ko'rsatuvchi port tekshiruvlari va cheklovlari davom etdi.[246]

The East India kompaniyasi kashfiyotlar narxlar va majburiyatlar Ningbo ikkalasi ham oldingidan ancha past edi Guanchjou ularni 1755 yilda shimolga siljitishni boshlashga undadi.[248] Keyingi Qianlong imperatori 1757 yil qishda u kelgusi yildan kuchga kirganini e'lon qildi. bitta getto janubi-g'arbda Guanchjou (keyin romanlashtirilgan G'arb savdogarlariga ruxsat berilgan yagona Xitoy porti bo'lishi kerak edi.[248][n 5] boshlanishi Kanton tizimi. Ushbu tizim asosida, a gildiya ning tasdiqlangan va bog'langan xitoylik savdogarlar chet ellik sheriklarining yaxshi xulq-atvori va soliqlarni to'lashini ta'minlash evaziga Xitoyning tashqi eksport savdosini monopollashtirdi. Mayers va Vang, ushbu cheklovlardan qat'i nazar, 1719 va 1806 yillarda Xitoy va Evropa o'rtasidagi savdo o'rtacha yillik 4 foizga o'sib, har 18 yilda bir marta savdo hajmini ikki baravarga oshirdi degan xulosaga kelishdi.[249] Bu Xitoyning ichki bozorlariga va uning qirg'oq bo'yidagi shahar portlariga yordam berdi va mahalliy mahsulotlarga qo'shimcha talabni ta'minladi. Ayniqsa, Guanchjouda mutaxassislik o'sdi chinni eksport qilish va Evropa omillari manfaatlariga javob beradigan eksport qilingan san'at asarlari. Guanchjou ba'zi a'zolari Cohong dunyodagi eng boy odamlar qatoriga kiritilgan; Howqua dan keyin Xitoy tomonidan amalga oshirilgan barcha qoplanishlarning uchdan bir qismini shaxsan o'z hissasiga qo'shgan Birinchi afyun urushi. Siyosat, shuningdek, Guanchjou soliq bazasini va chet eldan kumush kirib kelishini normallashtirdi, bu esa tashqi tomondan eng katta import sifatida saqlanib qoldi. Iqtisodiyotga bo'lgan doimiy ehtiyoj tufayli kumush milliy ahamiyatga ega bo'lgan resursga aylandi. Importni asosan cheklash orqali quyma ammo, bu kuchli bosimni yaratdi Inglizlar - choy kimga aylandi milliy ichimlik 18-asr davomida[250] - savdo balansini sozlash uchun har qanday vositani topish. Bir nechta elchixonalar xitoyliklarni qonuniy savdoni kengaytirishga ko'ndira olmaganidan so'ng, rad etish an'anaviy ravishda hisobga olinadi Makartni va boshqalarning rad etishlari kowtow yoki Xitoy protokolining boshqa o'ziga xos xususiyatlariga rioya qilsangiz, yechim kontrabanda yo'li bilan chiqdi Hind afyun. Hisob-kitoblarga ko'ra, 1821-1840 yillarda Xitoyda muomalada bo'lgan kumushning beshdan bir qismi afyun sotib olishga sarflangan.[251]

Li Siantangning so'zlariga ko'ra, kumush importi Xitoyni boyitdi, ammo bu kabi imkoniyatlarni ochmadi sanoat inqilobi Angliya va g'arbiy Evropada ochilgan edi. Buning o'rniga, Xitoy resurslarni haddan tashqari iste'mol qilishi sababli "yuqori muvozanat tuzog'iga" tushib ketdi. Xiantang ta'kidlaydi:

Aholi va daromadlarning o'sishi va iqtisodiyot va jamiyatning qutblanishi resurslarga bosimning kuchayishiga olib keldi. Bu jamiyatning quyi qismidagi talabni cheklab qo'ydi va Osiyoda arzon ishchi kuchini boshqa sohalarga qaraganda osonroq sotib olishga imkon berdi, ammo bu ishlab chiqarish va savdoning pasayishiga olib keldi .... Aynan shu qisqa muddatli farovonlik Xitoy xalqini bo'g'ib qo'ydi. Eng muhimi, kumush importi ibtidoiy hunarmandchilik sanoatining, ya'ni yangi boshlang'ich kapitalizmning gullab-yashnashiga yordam berdi va bu o'zini o'zi ta'minlaydigan kichik dehqonlar iqtisodiy tizimining so'nggi tiklanishi edi. Mavjud ishlab chiqarish munosabatlari doirasida kengayish orqali o'z tanazzulini to'xtatdi, ammo butun jamiyat "yuqori muvozanat tuzog'iga" tushdi. Kumush iqtisodiy g'ildiraklarni tezroq aylantirishga majbur qildi, ammo iqtisodiy rivojlanishning yangi institutsional paradigmasini ishlab chiqa olmadi.[252]

Qing ichki savdo

Qing hududi chegaralarida mintaqalararo va viloyatlararo savdo Ming va Song davrlarida rivojlangan bozor iqtisodiyoti asosida rivojlanib, kengayib borgan.[253] Qishloq, mintaqaviy va viloyatlararo darajadagi bozorlar o'rtasidagi savdo-sotiq sulola hududining katta qismini qamrab olgan tarmoqqa aylandi va ko'plab savdo markazlarini boyitdi. Suzhou. G'alla va paxta kabi asosiy tovarlarning provintsiyalar o'rtasidagi savdo-sotiq, ularning har biri ixtisoslashgan viloyatlarda o'stirilib, davlat atrofida jo'natilib, tovarlarni misli ko'rilmagan tezlikda Tsing chegaralari ichida olib o'tdi, bu esa Tsing sulolasi tomonidan ichki savdoga qo'yilgan ko'plab cheklovlarni bekor qilishi bilan rag'batlantirildi. savdo kartellari.[254]

An'anaviy Konfutsiylik doktrinasida bo'lgan savdogarlar, ular jamiyat ichida hech narsa yaratmaganliklari, yuqori ijtimoiy mavqega ega bo'lmaganliklari sababli, savdogarlar ushbu ichki savdo hisobidan nihoyatda boyib ketishdi. Mahalliy qishloq darajasidagi mayda savdogarlardan metropoliten savdo va ishlab chiqarish markazlari o'rtasida harakatlanadigan savdogarlargacha ko'plab savdogarlar sulolaning ichki savdosiga qo'shilishdi.[254] Ushbu savdogarlar, ko'pincha uchun o'qiganlar davlat xizmati imtihoni ammo post topolmadi yoki imtihondan o'ta olmadi, yangi kasbida boylik va farovonlikka erishdi.[255] Ko'pincha bu savdogarlarning ko'plari savdo gildiyalarini, savdo markazlari, xususan boy metropolitan savdo markazlari tarkibidagi ishbilarmonlarning konglomeratsiyalarini yaratish uchun birlashdilar. Ushbu gildiyalar, past darajadagi an'anaviy mavqelariga qaramay, o'zlarining shahar markazlarini o'zgartirish uchun kuchli kuchga aylanib, xayriya ishlarida qatnashdilar va shaharni saqlashga hissa qo'shdilar.[254] Metropolitan yadrolari ichida gullab-yashnayotgan qudratidan tashqari, ushbu savdogarlar o'zlarining boyliklaridan Qing iyerarxiyasida olimlar sifatida litsenziya sotib olish orqali ijtimoiy mavqega ega bo'lishlari uchun ham foydalanishgan va shu bilan o'zlarini Konfutsiy iyerarxik tizimida ko'tarishgan.[256]

Garchi ba'zi viloyatlar va hududlar o'z mahsulotlarini paxta yoki oziq-ovqat mahsulotlari kabi talab yuqori bo'lgan asosiy ekinlarga yo'naltira boshlagan bo'lsa-da, boshqalari naqd paxta ekinlari ishlab chiqarishni ko'paytirdilar, bu esa ipak to'qimachilik yoki chinni buyumlar kabi mahsulotlar uchun mahalliy ishlab chiqarish omborlarini rivojlantirishga turtki bo'ldi. .[254]

Tsinning iqtisodiy qulashi

Uning qobiliyatsiz ta'siriga qaramay,[251] bo'yicha mavjud taqiqlar Xitoyda afyun savdosi ga qadar umuman e'tiborga olinmadi 1833 yil Hindiston hukumati to'g'risidagi qonun yo'q qildi East India kompaniyasi Buyuk Britaniyaning Xitoy bilan savdo-sotiq monopoliyasi. Britaniyalik rasmiylarning ta'kidlashicha, yangi kontrabandachilarning cheklanmagan oqimi xitoyliklarni juda xavotirga solgan, ammo ularni jilovlashdan oldin jilovlay olmagan. noib Lin Zexu joylashtirilgan chet el fabrikalari Pearl River deltasida o'tkazilgan barcha afyunlarning taslim bo'lishini talab qilib, to'liq blokada ostida. Britaniyaliklar buni o'zlarining boshlig'i zararni qoplash uchun kafolat bergandan keyingina ta'minlay olishdi. Bu summa juda katta bo'lib chiqdi (£ Ga undagan Birinchi afyun urushi,[257] 1842 yil Nanking shartnomasi - ning boshlanishi teng bo'lmagan shartnomalar 19-asrda Tsing suverenitetini cheklagan - odatda portlar ochilishi bilan Xitoyning izolyatsiyasini tugatdi. Xiamen ("Amoy"), Fuzhou ("Fuchow"), Ningbo ("Ningpo") va Shanxay, lekin qonuniy savdo belgilangan vaqtgacha belgilangan portlar bilan chegaralanishda davom etdi sulolaning oxiri. Shunga qaramay, urush urush, mag'lubiyat, imtiyozlar va kompensatsiyalarning namunasini boshladi va kumushning chiqishi natijasida Xitoy hukumati va iqtisodiyotini yanada zaiflashtirdi.[258]

Qingning imtiyozlaridan g'azablanish va ularning kuchsizligidan ajablanish allaqachon 1850-yillarning boshlarida sodir bo'lgan suv toshqini oldidan qo'zg'olonlarni qo'zg'atgan, xususan, og'zini o'zgartirgan Sariq daryo janubidan Shandun uning shimolidagi yarim orol - vayron bo'lgan va millionlab odamlarni ko'chirgan. 1851 yilda, Hong Syuquan Tsin sulolasiga qarshi qo'zg'olonni boshlab, uning hukmdorlarini "Xitoyni umidsizlikka olib kelgan" iflos barbarlar va hayvonlar "deb e'lon qildi. Uning Taiping isyoni tezda Xitoyning janubi-sharqiy qismini o'z qo'liga oldi.[259] Inglizlar va frantsuzlarning yordami bilan Qing isyonchilarni mag'lubiyatga uchratdi, ammo bu 20 milliondan ortiq odamning hayotiga sarflandi. 1871 yilgacha davom etgan Taiping isyoni tarixdagi eng qonli urushlardan biri edi va Qing iqtisodiyotini vayron qildi, bu mamlakatning boshlanishi bilan yordam bermadi Ikkinchi afyun urushi 1856 yilda.[260] Shu bilan birga, Oltishahr va Tarim havzasi maydonlari Shinjon Xitoyning shimoliy g'arbiy qismida imperator xazinasini yanada to'kkanligi isbotlandi. Shinjonda tartibni ta'minlash uchun armiya garnizonlarini saqlash va uning qo'shimcha ma'muriyati o'n minglab xarajatlarni talab qildi poyabzal har yili kumush, bu esa boy viloyatlarda olinadigan qishloq xo'jaligi soliqlaridan subsidiyalarni talab qildi.[261]

Taypin qo'zg'olonidan keyin ba'zi manjur zodagonlari islohotlar zarurligini tan olishdi. Ular asos solgan O'z-o'zini mustahkamlash harakati birinchi navbatda Xitoyning harbiy sanoatiga qaratilgan cheklangan modernizatsiyani amalga oshirdi. Armiya jihozlanib, zamonaviy harbiy dengiz floti rivojlandi. Manjur dvoryanlarining aksariyati ushbu o'zgarishlarga, shu jumladan, ularga hamroh bo'lgan cheklangan sanoatlashtirishga qarshi chiqdilar.[262] 1894 yilda yaponlar mag'lub bo'lganidan so'ng, harakat obro'sizlanib qoldi. 1911 yilda Sinxay inqilobi manjurlarni ag'darib tashladi va Xitoy Respublikasi. Jangarilar va fuqarolar urushi boshchiligidagi davr Xitoy iqtisodiyotining tanazzulini tezlashtirdi yalpi ichki mahsulot tez tushib ketdi,[263] garchi o'sha paytda Evropa va Qo'shma Shtatlar ham o'tdi Sanoat va Texnologik inqilob bu ularning ulushiga sakrab tushdi.[8]Ushbu davrdagi turmush darajasi past bo'lgan bo'lsa ham, Xitoy aholisining hisoblash darajasi - bu jamiyatning raqamli ko'nikmalarini o'lchaydigan va keyingi iqtisodiy rivojlanish bilan kuchli bog'liqlikni ko'rsatadigan indeks - Evropaning shimoliy-g'arbiy mamlakatlari va shu sababli dunyodagi eng baland. Xitoy xalqining inson kapitali salohiyati va shu bilan solishtirganda past turmush darajasi o'rtasidagi farq bu siyosiy va ijtimoiy beqaror davrning Xitoy iqtisodiyotiga salbiy ta'sirini ta'kidlaydi va shuningdek, Xitoy biron bir davrni boshidan kechirgan paytda paydo bo'ladigan portlovchi iqtisodiy o'sishni tushuntiradi. ichki tinchlik.[264]

Evropa ta'siri

Ikki urushda Xitoyni mag'lubiyatga uchratgandan so'ng, Buyuk Britaniya unga va boshqa imperatorlik kuchlari, shu jumladan Frantsiya va Germaniya, shuningdek, AQSh va Yaponiya uchun alohida huquqlar yaratadigan shartnomalarni ta'minladi. Ular bir qator "shartnoma portlari" ni, xususan, Shanxayni o'z nazoratiga olishdi. Asosiy maqsad savdo edi, ammo port shaharlari Xitoy iqtisodiyoti, jamiyati va madaniyatiga uzoq muddatli katta ta'sir ko'rsatdi. Eng avvalo Shanxay shahar markaziga aylandi. Tyantszin va Shenyan ergashdilar; Gonkong, garchi Britaniyaning mustamlakasi shartnoma porti bo'lmagan bo'lsa ham. Xristian missionerlari kabi chet elliklar kutib olindi va barqaror xavfsiz bazalarga ega edi. Portlardan tashqarida faqat chet elliklar vaqti-vaqti bilan xristian missionerlari bo'lgan va ular ko'pincha jiddiy qiyinchiliklarga duch kelishgan. 1842-1914 yillarda shartnoma portiga aylangan boshqa 89 shahar unchalik katta ahamiyatga ega emas edi.[265][266]

19-asr oxiridagi Yaponiyaning keskin tezkor modernizatsiyasidan keskin farq qilib, Xitoyning manjur rahbarlari konservativ yo'lni tutdilar. 1871 yilda Xitoyning tashqi dunyo bilan aloqalari keskin o'zgargan Buyuk Shimoliy telegraf kompaniyasi Shanxayni Gonkong, Singapur, Nagasaki va Vladivostok bilan bog'laydigan, Hindiston va Evropaga ulangan kabellarni ochdi. Xitoy ichidagi birinchi telegraf, shu bilan birga, 1881 yilda ochilgan Shanxay va Tyantszin o'rtasidagi qisqa chiziq edi.[267][268] Xitoyning Yaponiya bilan birinchi zamonaviy tijorat shartnomasi 1871 yilda tenglik asosida imzolandi. O'zining diplomatik ochilishi doirasida Xitoy 1877–1880 yillarda Tokio, London, Berlin, Vashington, Madrid va Sankt-Peterburgda legionlar tashkil qildi. Har bir inson Xitoyning yuz millionlab iste'molchilari bilan yuqori rentabellikdagi savdo-sotiqdan umidvor bo'lgan. Bu sodir bo'lmadi. 1890 yilga kelib barcha tashqi import va eksportlarning umumiy qiymati atigi 50 million funtni tashkil etdi, bu ko'plab kichik mamlakatlarga qaraganda kamroq. Evropa uni chinni va ipakka ega qildi; Xitoy o'z afyunini o'stirdi. Yagona asosiy yangi mahsulot Amerikaning Standard Oil kompaniyasi tomonidan olib kelingan kerosin (lampalar uchun) edi. Xitoy juda qashshoq, o'zini o'zi ta'minlaydigan va foydali savdo aloqalari uchun temir yo'llarda etishmayotgan edi.[269] [270]

Muhim modernizatsiya Shanxay, Gonkong va ozroq darajada boshqa port shaharlarida sodir bo'ldi. The Shanxay xalqaro aholi punkti tez Parij, Berlin va London bilan taqqoslaganda dunyodagi eng zamonaviy shaharlardan biriga aylandi.[271] Bu Xitoy va butun Sharqiy Osiyo uchun zamonaviylik standartini o'rnatdi. Shanxayda ingliz va amerikalik aholi punktlari 1863 yilda xalqaro aholi punktiga qo'shilib, frantsuz aholi punkti yaqin atrofda alohida ish yuritgan. Chet elliklar erni uzoq muddatli ijaraga olib, fabrikalar, idoralar, omborlar, sanitariya, politsiya, bog'lar, restoranlar, mehmonxonalar, banklar va xususiy klublar tashkil etishgan. The Shanxay shahar kengashi 1854 yilda tashkil topgan bo'lib, to'qqiz a'zodan iborat bo'lib, ular dastlab o'nlab xorijiy er egalari tomonidan va 1920-yillarda 2000 ga yaqin saylovchilar tomonidan saylangan. Xitoy aholisi Shanxayning umumiy aholisining 90 foizini tashkil etdi, ammo vakolatisiz soliqqa tortish to'g'risida shikoyat qildilar. Oxir oqibat Kengash beshta Xitoy vakilini qabul qildi.[272]

Evropa hamjamiyati o'sib borayotgan mamlakat bo'ylab o'z shaharlari uchun namuna sifatida xitoylik tadbirkorlar uchun ayniqsa jozibador bo'lgan texnologik va iqtisodiy yangiliklarni hamda bilim sohalarini ilgari surdi.[273] Port shaharlar qator etakchilik rollarini birlashtirdi. Avvalo ular boshqa import va eksport uchun asosiy kirish porti bo'lgan - afyun bundan mustasno, boshqa shaharlarda kontrabandachilar bilan shug'ullangan.[274] Chet ellik tadbirkorlar Evropaning eng so'nggi ishlab chiqarish usullarini joriy etadilar, ertami-kechmi butun Xitoy tomonidan qo'llaniladigan modelni taqdim etadilar. Dastlabki korxonalar kema qurish, kemalarni ta'mirlash, temir yo'llarni ta'mirlash va to'qimachilik, gugurt, chinni, un va mashinasozlik ishlab chiqaradigan fabrikalarga yo'naltirilgan. Kantonda tamaki, sigaretalar, to'qimachilik va oziq-ovqat mahsulotlari ixtisoslashgan edi. Moliyalashtirish filial banklari tomonidan amalga oshirildi, shuningdek, bu kabi yangi operatsiyalar HSBC - Gongkong va Shanxay bank korporatsiyasi, bu XXI asrga qadar jahon darajasidagi muassasa bo'lib qolmoqda.[275] Modernizatsiya qilinadigan dunyo bo'ylab temir yo'l qurilishi odatda inglizlar boshchiligidagi yirik moliyaviy va sanoat ishi edi. Endi sarmoyalar Xitoyni bir-biriga bog'laydigan temir yo'l-plyus-telegraf tizimini qurishga, shartnoma portlarini va boshqa yirik shaharlarni hamda konchilik tumanlari va qishloq xo'jaligi markazlarini birlashtirdi.[276] Xitoylik tadbirkorlar o'zlarining malakalarini port shaharlarida o'rganishdi va tez orada o'zlarining boshlang'ich tashkilotlari uchun bank kreditlarini olish uchun ariza topshirdilar va oldilar. Bosh ofisi joylashgan xitoylik savdogarlar Janubi-Sharqiy Osiyo bo'ylab, shu jumladan Britaniya Singapur va Malaya, Gollandiyaning Sharqiy Hindistoni, Frantsuz Hind-Xitoy va Amerika Filippinlari bo'ylab o'z filiallarini ochdilar.[277]

Port shaharlarida axborot sanoati rivojlanib, xitoy va yevropa tillarida bosmaxona, gazeta, jurnal va risolalar paydo bo'ldi. Kitob nashriyotlari ko'pincha falsafa, siyosat, adabiyot va ijtimoiy mavzulardagi Evropa klassiklarining xitoycha tarjimalarini namoyish etdilar.[278] Tarixchi Klaus Muhlxannning so'zlariga ko'ra:

Markazi Shanxay bo'lgan ushbu ulkan tarmoq Xitoy shahar aholisining o'zgarishiga turtki bo'ldi. Shahar aholisining o'qimishli va badavlat guruhlari o'zlarining fikrlari, didlari va kundalik faoliyatlarida an'anaviy turmush tarzidan voz kechishni boshladilar va zamonaviy hayot tarzi deb bilgan narsalarini qabul qila boshladilar.[279]

Xristian missionerlari barcha Xitoy aholisini o'zlarining maqsadli auditoriyalari deb bildilar, ammo ularning shtab-kvartirasi port shaharlarida joylashgan. Missionerlar xitoyliklarni konvertatsiya qilishda juda kam yutuqlarga erishdilar, ammo ular tibbiyot va ta'lim muassasalarini tashkil qilishda keng ommalashganligini aniqladilar. Masalan Shanxaydagi Sent-Jon universiteti (1879-1952) dastlab ilohiyot fakultetlarini, g'arb tillarini o'rganish va xitoy tillarini ochdi, keyin adabiyot, fan, tibbiyot va g'arb tillarini qattiq qamrab olish uchun kengayib, sobiq Konfutsiyni rad etgan shuhratparast xitoy ziyolilari va tadbirkorlari tomonidan izlandi. G'arbning zamonaviy modeli uchun imtihon tizimi. Shuningdek, muhandislik maktablari tashkil etildi va 1914 yilga kelib universitetlar, kollejlar, o'qituvchilarni tayyorlash maktablari va ixtisoslashtirilgan sanoat maktablari tarmog'i Port shaharlarida joylashgan bo'lib, ularning bitiruvchilari butun shahar bo'ylab tarqalib ketishdi.[280]

Talabalar port shaharlariga to'kilgan. Ko'pchilik g'oyalarni qabul qildilar va ular uchun yangi ochilgan imkoniyatlardan bir-biri bilan aloqa o'rnatish, tashkilotlar va nashrlarni tashkil qilish va Tsin hukumatiga qarshi inqilobni amalga oshirish uchun foydalandilar. Birinchi jahon urushida Yaponiyaning agressiv harakatlari Xitoyda hukmronlik qilishga intildi To'rtinchi harakat o'z g'azabini nafaqat Yaponiyaga, balki butun port shaharlar tizimiga yo'naltirdi, bu endi toqat qilinmasligi kerak bo'lgan imperializmning timsolidir.[281] Milliy hukumat port shaharlarida deyarli hech qanday politsiya kuchiga ega emas edi, bu xitoy jamoasida yashirin jamiyatlarning rivojlanishiga imkon berdi, ularning ba'zilari jinoiy to'dalarga aylandi. Oxir oqibat Shanxayda zo'ravonlik ishlatishga tayyor bo'lgan kuchli yer osti noqonuniy jinoyati mavjud edi.[282]

Shuningdek qarang

Izohlar

  1. ^ Adam Smit Xitoy 18 asrga qadar uzoq vaqt harakatsiz bo'lgan deb o'ylardi. Shiue va boshq. 1750 yilda Xitoyning eng rivojlangan mintaqalari hali ham Atlantika bilan chegaradosh Evropa davlatlari bilan bir qatorda mahsuldorlikni namoyish etganligini ta'kidlaydilar,[5] esa Maddison G'arbiy Evropaning jon boshiga hosildorligi bu davrda barcha mintaqalardan ustun bo'lganligini ta'kidlaydi.[6]
  2. ^ Masalan, Bodde,[9] u talqin qilganiga e'tibor bering "feodalizm "iqtisodiy tizim emas, balki boshqaruv usuli sifatida.[10]
  3. ^ Tizimga xitoycha belgi nomi berilgan (jing, "yaxshi "), bu to'qqizta maydon taxmin qilingan tartibda joylashtirilgan panjara o'xshash naqshga o'xshaydi.[43]
  4. ^ Tang Chen shunday deb yozgan edi: The asos solinganiga ellik yildan oshdi Ching sulolasi va imperiya har kuni qashshoqlashmoqda. Dehqonlar qashshoq, hunarmandlar qashshoq, savdogarlar qashshoq, amaldorlar ham qashshoq. Don arzon, shunga qaramay, to'yib ovqat eyish qiyin. Mato arzon, ammo terini qoplash qiyin. Qayiq yuklari bir bozordan ikkinchisiga sayohat qiladi, ammo yuklar zarar bilan sotilishi kerak. Amaldorlar o'z lavozimlaridan ketayotib, o'z uylarini boqish uchun imkoniyatlari yo'qligini aniqladilar. Haqiqatan ham to'rt kasb hammasi qashshoq![227]
  5. ^ Alohida siyosat va shartnomalar asosida, Koreyslar va Yapon bilan savdo qilingan Yapu yaqin Xanchjou va Ruslar bilan to'g'ridan-to'g'ri birinchi bo'lib savdoga qo'yilgan Pekin va keyin chegara o'tish punktida Kyaxta.

Adabiyotlar

Iqtiboslar

  1. ^ Hindiston va bilim iqtisodiyoti: kuchli va imkoniyatlardan foydalanish. Jahon banki. 2005-01-01. p. 131. ISBN  9780821362082.
  2. ^ Dalman, Karl J; Obert, Jan-Erik. Xitoy va bilimlar iqtisodiyoti: XXI asrni egallash. WBI rivojlanish tadqiqotlari. Jahon banki nashrlar. Kirish 2008 yil 30-yanvar.
  3. ^ Angus Meddison. Uzoq muddatda Xitoyning iqtisodiy ko'rsatkichlari Arxivlandi 2014-10-15 da Orqaga qaytish mashinasi. Rivojlanish markazini o'rganish. Kirish 2007. s.29 "1.3-jadval. Xitoy va Evropa YaIMning aholi jon boshiga, 1-1700 milodiy odamlarga to'g'ri keladigan darajasi" ga qarang, 29-bet, Xitoyning Aholi jon boshiga YaIM 450 va 960AD yilda Evropaning kapitaliga 422 edi. Aholi jon boshiga Xitoy YaIM 600, Evropaliklar esa 576 tani tashkil etdi. Shu vaqt ichida xitoylik aholi jon boshiga daromadi qariyb uchdan biriga oshdi.
  4. ^ a b v d Bodde (1987), p. 54
  5. ^ Shiue, Kerol X.; va boshq., ?, NBER.
  6. ^ Maddison, Angus (2006), Jahon iqtisodiyoti. Ming yillik istiqbol, Tarixiy statistika, Jild II, jild Men, OECD, p. 629, ISBN  978-92-64-02261-4.
  7. ^ Lands, Devid S. (1998), Xalqlarning boyligi va qashshoqligi: nega ba'zilari juda boy va ba'zilari kambag'al, Nyu-York: W.W. Norton & Co., s.29–44, ISBN  978-0-393-04017-3.
  8. ^ a b Pomeranz, Kennet (2001). Katta kelishmovchilik: Xitoy, Evropa va zamonaviy jahon iqtisodiyotini yaratish. Prinston universiteti matbuoti. ISBN  9780691090108.
  9. ^ a b Bodde (1956), 49ff
  10. ^ Rikket (1987), p. 15.
  11. ^ Ji va boshq (2005a), p. 39.
  12. ^ Bodde (1987), p. 22.
  13. ^ Chang (1999), 42-47 betlar.
  14. ^ Chang (1999), 43, 46-betlar.
  15. ^ Bray (1984), 40-43 betlar.
  16. ^ Kun (1988), p. 93
  17. ^ Kun (1988), 271-72-betlar
  18. ^ Chang (1999), p. 60.
  19. ^ a b Chang (1999), 72-73 betlar.
  20. ^ Bagli (1999), 158-65-betlar.
  21. ^ Bagli (1999), 156, 158-betlar.
  22. ^ a b Bagli (1999), p. 164.
  23. ^ a b v Bagli (1999), p. 157.
  24. ^ Bagli (1999), p. 133.
  25. ^ Bagli (1999), p. 165.
  26. ^ a b Bagli (1999), p. 158.
  27. ^ Bagli (1999), 155-56 betlar.
  28. ^ Keightley (1999), 277-78 betlar.
  29. ^ Chang (1963), p. 172.
  30. ^ Keightley (1999), p. 278.
  31. ^ Keightley (1999), p. 280.
  32. ^ Ji va boshq (2005a), p. 24.
  33. ^ a b Bray (1984), p. 95.
  34. ^ Keightley (1999), p. 279.
  35. ^ Keightley (1999), 279-80 betlar.
  36. ^ Kun (1988), p. 142.
  37. ^ Kun (1982), 399-401 betlar.
  38. ^ Keightley (1999), p. 286.
  39. ^ Keightley (1999), 282–88, 285–86-betlar.
  40. ^ Shahesnessy (1999), p. 327.
  41. ^ Li (2007), 113-17 betlar.
  42. ^ Shahesnessy (1999), p. 328.
  43. ^ Xsu (1999), p. 576.
  44. ^ Bray (1984), p. 101.
  45. ^ Lyuis (1999), p. 605.
  46. ^ Xsu (1999), 576-77 betlar.
  47. ^ Li (2007), 101-06 betlar.
  48. ^ Li va Zheng (2001).
  49. ^ Ji va boshq (2005a), p. 32.
  50. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 108.
  51. ^ Xogan, S Maykl (2011), "Oltingugurt", Yer entsiklopediyasi, Vashington: Ilmiy va atrof-muhit bo'yicha Nat'l kengashi.
  52. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 147.
  53. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 146.
  54. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 144.
  55. ^ Tsu va Griffit (2006), 37-47 betlar.
  56. ^ Nishijima (1986), p. 546
  57. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), 189-90 betlar.
  58. ^ Nishijima (1986), p. 556.
  59. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 212.
  60. ^ a b v Li va Zheng (2001), p. 310
  61. ^ a b Bodde (1987), p. 84
  62. ^ Bodde (1987), p. 61
  63. ^ Jan (2006)
  64. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), 235-308 betlar
  65. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 241
  66. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 243
  67. ^ a b Loewe (1987), p. 150
  68. ^ Ji va boshq (2005a), 73-75 betlar
  69. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 244
  70. ^ Nishijima (1986), 596-98 betlar
  71. ^ Ji va boshq (2005a), p. 70
  72. ^ Loewe (1986), 187–206-betlar
  73. ^ a b v Nishijima (1986), 587-88 betlar
  74. ^ a b v d e f g h Nishijima, Sadao. (1986). 22.
  75. ^ Xinsh (2002), 21-22 betlar
  76. ^ Vagner (2001b), 73-bet
  77. ^ a b Vagner (2001b), 15-17 betlar
  78. ^ Vagner (2001b), 13-14 betlar
  79. ^ Nishijima (1986), p. 600
  80. ^ Nishijima (1986), p. 582
  81. ^ Ji va boshq (2005a), p. 78
  82. ^ a b Li va Zheng (2001), 282–84-betlar
  83. ^ Ebrey (1999), p. 75
  84. ^ Nishijima (1986), 586-87 betlar
  85. ^ Ebrey (1986), p. 609
  86. ^ Bilenshteyn (1987), 232-33 betlar
  87. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 254
  88. ^ Bilenshteyn (1987), p. 238
  89. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), 295–99 betlar
  90. ^ Ebrey (1999), 60-62 betlar
  91. ^ a b Ebrey (1999), p. 62
  92. ^ Ji va boshq (2005a), p. 111
  93. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), 409–11-betlar
  94. ^ Jin kitobi, 421–427
  95. ^ a b Li va Zheng (2001), 428-34-betlar
  96. ^ a b Qo'shiq kitobi, Ming Ti
  97. ^ "Song Song" kitobi, Ven Ti
  98. ^ Xu (2005)
  99. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), 428-52 betlar
  100. ^ a b Li va Zheng (2001), p. 459
  101. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), 459-81 betlar
  102. ^ a b Li va Zheng (2001), p. 548
  103. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 554
  104. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 588
  105. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 589
  106. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 561
  107. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), 585-87 betlar
  108. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), 562-68 betlar
  109. ^ Ebrey (2006), p. 91
  110. ^ Ebrey (2006), p. 92
  111. ^ Ji va boshq (2005b), p. 27
  112. ^ Ji va boshq (2005b), p. 17
  113. ^ a b v d e f g Xie (2005)
  114. ^ Ji va boshq (2005b), p. 30
  115. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 679
  116. ^ a b Ebrey (2006), p. 100
  117. ^ Benn (2002), 15-17 betlar
  118. ^ a b Ji va boshq (2005), p. 34
  119. ^ Shafer (1963), p. 9
  120. ^ Edgren, J. S. (2007): "G'arbdan tashqaridagi kitob": Xitoy, In: Eliot, Simon; Rose, Jonathan (tahr.): Kitob tarixining sherigi, Blackwell Publishing, pp.97 102110 (102), ISBN  978-1-4051-2765-3
  121. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 697
  122. ^ Twitchett va Klaus-Peter (1995), 54
  123. ^ a b v d Twitchett and Klaus-Peter (1995), 55-56 betlar
  124. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), 777-88-betlar
  125. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 777
  126. ^ Tvithet va Klaus-Piter (1995), 38
  127. ^ Broadberry, Stiven; Guan, Xanxuey; Daokui, Devid (dekabr 2018). "Xitoy, Evropa va buyuk xilma-xillik: tarixiy milliy buxgalteriya hisobi, 980–1850" (PDF). Iqtisodiy tarix jurnali. 78 (4): 955–1000. doi:10.1017 / S0022050718000529.
  128. ^ Rossabi (1986), p. 76
  129. ^ a b Xobson (2005), p. 77
  130. ^ Vagner (2001), 176
  131. ^ Ebrey (2003), p. 104
  132. ^ Vagner (2001), 181.
  133. ^ Du (1998), p. 45
  134. ^ Du (1998), p. 46
  135. ^ Needham (1985), p. 126
  136. ^ Smit (1993), p. 77
  137. ^ Ebrey (1993), p. 164
  138. ^ a b Ji va boshq (2005b), 62-64 betlar
  139. ^ Du (1998), p. 44
  140. ^ Qi (1999), p. 65
  141. ^ Dji (1997), 124-29 betlar
  142. ^ Ebrey (1986), p. 141
  143. ^ Ji va boshq (2005b), p. 60
  144. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 877
  145. ^ a b Ji va boshq (2005b), p. 61
  146. ^ a b Du (1998), p. 40
  147. ^ Ji va boshq (2005b), p. 62
  148. ^ Ebrey, Walthall & Palais (2006), p. 157
  149. ^ Ji va boshq (2005b), p. 73
  150. ^ Golas, Piter (1980), "Qishloqdagi Xitoy qo'shiqda", Osiyo tadqiqotlari jurnali, 39 (2): 291–325, doi:10.2307/2054291, JSTOR  2054291.
  151. ^ Embri (1997), p. 339
  152. ^ Embri (1997), 339-40 betlar
  153. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), 878-80 betlar
  154. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 879
  155. ^ Ebrey (2001), p. 103
  156. ^ Rossabi (1988), 77-78 betlar
  157. ^ Nishijima (1986), p. 588
  158. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 880
  159. ^ Needham (1985), p. 47
  160. ^ Gernet (1962), p. 80
  161. ^ Ji va boshq (2005b), p. 52
  162. ^ Ji va boshq (2005b), p. 70
  163. ^ Ji va boshq (2005), p. 83
  164. ^ Ebrey (1986), p. 150
  165. ^ Franke (1994), p. 232
  166. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 811
  167. ^ Franke (1995), p. 265
  168. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 865
  169. ^ Rossabi (1995), p. 459
  170. ^ Ji va boshq (2005b), p. 72
  171. ^ "Qora tuyalar va otashin murvatlar: Mamluk armiyasida murvatni loyihalashtiruvchi trebuchet", Mamluk tadqiqotlari sharhi Vol. 8/1, 2004, 227-77 betlar (232ff.)
  172. ^ Rossabi (1995), p. 435
  173. ^ Franke (1994), p. 42
  174. ^ a b Franke (1994), p. 36
  175. ^ Dardess (1995), p. 621
  176. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 925
  177. ^ Rossabi (1995), 454-55 betlar
  178. ^ Rossabi (1995), p. 488
  179. ^ Rossabi (1995), p. 471
  180. ^ Rossabi (1995), 473-75-betlar
  181. ^ Rossabi (1995), p. 479
  182. ^ Hsiao (1994), p. 492
  183. ^ Hsiao (1995), p. 491
  184. ^ Rossabi (1995), p. 476
  185. ^ Dreyer (1988), 88-94 betlar
  186. ^ Dreyer (1988), p. 96
  187. ^ Mote (1988), p. 11
  188. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 950
  189. ^ a b Mote (1988), p. 4
  190. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 994
  191. ^ Atuell (2002), p. 84
  192. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 961
  193. ^ Ji & va boshqalar (2005c), p. 17
  194. ^ Mote (1988), p. 3
  195. ^ a b Xuang (1988), 110-13 betlar
  196. ^ a b v Li va Zheng (2001), p. 996
  197. ^ Twitchett va boshq (1988), 110-13 bet
  198. ^ Xuang (1988), p. 138
  199. ^ Xuang (1988), p. 144
  200. ^ Xuang (1988), 144-48 betlar
  201. ^ Xuang (1988), p. 141
  202. ^ Bruk (1998), p. 206
  203. ^ Von Glen, Richard (1996), Boylik favvorasi: 1000–1700 yillarda Xitoyda pul va pul-kredit siyosati, Berkli: Kaliforniya universiteti matbuoti, p.90, ISBN  978-0-520-20408-9.
  204. ^ Li Kangying (2010), O'tishdagi Ming dengiz savdo siyosati, 1368 yildan 1567 yilgacha, Visbaden: Otto Xarrassovits, p.3, ISBN  9783447061728.
  205. ^ Von Glen (1996), p.116.
  206. ^ Baten, Yorg (2016). Jahon iqtisodiyoti tarixi. 1500 yildan hozirgi kungacha. Kembrij universiteti matbuoti. p. 39. ISBN  9781107507180.
  207. ^ Von Glen (1996), p.91.
  208. ^ Fairbank (2006), p. 134
  209. ^ Atwell (1988), p. 387
  210. ^ Bruk (1998), 68-69, 81-83 betlar
  211. ^ Ebrey (2001), p. 140
  212. ^ Fairbank (2006), 134-35 betlar
  213. ^ Maddison, Angus (2007): "Jahon iqtisodiyotining konturlari, milodiy 1–2030 yillar. Makroiqtisodiyot tarixidagi esselar", Oksford universiteti matbuoti, ISBN  978-0-19-922721-1, p. 382, jadval A.7.
  214. ^ Pomeranz (2000), 62-66 bet
  215. ^ Liang (1981), p. 43
  216. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), 994-95-betlar
  217. ^ a b v d Heijdra (1988), 497-98 betlar
  218. ^ Heijdra (1988), p. 527
  219. ^ Heijdra (1988), 517-18 betlar
  220. ^ Heijdra (1988), p. 580
  221. ^ a b Mote (1988), p. 6
  222. ^ Uilyam S. Atuell, "Xitoyga kumush importiga yana bir qarash, taxminan 1635-1644". Jahon tarixi jurnali (2005): 467-489 onlayn.
  223. ^ Billi K. L. Shunday qilib, ed., Kech imperatorlik qilgan Xitoyda Quyi Yangzi deltasi iqtisodiyoti: pul, bozorlar va muassasalarni bir-biriga bog'lash (2012) 4, 17-18, 32-34 betlar. parcha
  224. ^ Spens (1999), p. 33
  225. ^ Vakeman (1985), 646-50 betlar
  226. ^ Li va Zheng (2001), p. 1017
  227. ^ Myers & Vang (2002), p. 565.
  228. ^ Myers & Vang (2002), p. 564
  229. ^ Fairbank (1978), 33-34 betlar
  230. ^ Fairbank (1978), p. 33
  231. ^ "Xitoyda kartoshka ishlab chiqarish to'g'risida ma'lumot". Qishloq xo'jaligi va tabiiy resurslar antropologiya laboratoriyasi, Jorjiya universiteti, Afina, AQSh. Arxivlandi asl nusxasi 2010 yil 6 martda. Olingan 21 dekabr, 2009.
  232. ^ Fairbank (1978), p. 191
  233. ^ a b Murphey (2007), p. 151.
  234. ^ Myers & Wang (2003), 606-07 betlar
  235. ^ Myers & Wang (2003), p. 609
  236. ^ http://www.sciea.org/data-j01/05_Articles3_Matsuura.pdf p. 62.
  237. ^ http://www.ari.nus.edu.sg/wps/wps08_106.pdf
  238. ^ Shottenxammer, Anjela. ""Yaponiya - mitti mitti? Kangxi-dan erta Tsianlun hukmronligiga qadar bo'lgan xitoy-yapon aloqalari ", Angela Shottenxammerda (tahr.), Sharqiy Osiyo O'rta er dengizi - madaniyat, savdo va inson migratsiyasining dengiz chorrahasi (Visbaden: Otto Harrassovits, 2008), 331-388. Sharqiy Osiyo dengiz tarixi, 6 ". Iqtibos jurnali talab qiladi | jurnal = (Yordam bering)
  239. ^ https://openaccess.leidenuniv.nl/bitstream/handle/1887/20013/02.pdf?sequence=7 p. 22.
  240. ^ http://scholarspace.manoa.hawaii.edu/bitstream/handle/10125/23059/%2353_Bun.pdf?sequence=1 p. 40.
  241. ^ https://openaccess.leidenuniv.nl/bitstream/handle/1887/20013/FDGbookFinalCompacted.pdf?sequence=21 p. 22.
  242. ^ http://www.univ-paris-diderot.fr/eacs-easl/DocumentsFCK/file/BOA14juin.pdf Arxivlandi 2016-06-10 at the Orqaga qaytish mashinasi p. 75.
  243. ^ Micklethwait (2003), p. 7.
  244. ^ a b v d Shi (2006), p.8.
  245. ^ Hayes (1974), p. 119.
  246. ^ a b v Shi (2006), p.9.
  247. ^ The muhojirlar jamoasi yilda Jakarta was estimated at 100,000.[246]
  248. ^ a b Shi (2006), p.10.
  249. ^ Myers & Wang (2003), p. 587
  250. ^ "Tea". Bizning vaqtimizda. 2004 yil 29 aprel. BBC radiosi 4.
  251. ^ a b Compilation Group, History of Modern China, 2000, p. 17.
  252. ^ Li Xiantang, "The Paradoxical Effect of Silver in the Economies of Ming and Qing China: On the New Myth Created by the 'Global Economic View' of Andre Gunder Frank and Kenneth Pomeranz." Tarix bo'yicha xitoyshunoslik 45.1 (2011): 84-99, quoting p. 97.
  253. ^ Jonathan, Porter (2016). Imperial Xitoy, 1350-1900 yillar. Lanham. ISBN  9781442222922. OCLC  920818520.
  254. ^ a b v d T., Rou, Uilyam (2009). Xitoyning so'nggi imperiyasi: buyuk Tsin. Kembrij, Mass.: Garvard universiteti matbuotining Belknap matbuoti. ISBN  9780674036123. OCLC  648759723.
  255. ^ Jonathan, Porter (2016). Imperial Xitoy, 1350-1900 yillar. Lanham. ISBN  9781442222922. OCLC  920818520.
  256. ^ Hu, Minghui. Lecture, HIS 140B, History of Qing China, UC Santa Cruz, February 21, 2018
  257. ^ "Commercial Intercourse with China", Barcha kitobxonlar uchun ritsarning bilim do'koni, London: Charles Knight & Co., 1841, p. 148.
  258. ^ Fairbank (1978), pp. 213–16.
  259. ^ Li & Zheng (2001), p. 1049.
  260. ^ Sun (2000), p. 712.
  261. ^ Tanner (2010), p. 368.
  262. ^ Sun (2000), p. 610.
  263. ^ Sun (2000), p. 611.
  264. ^ Baten, Yorg (2016). Jahon iqtisodiyoti tarixi. 1500 yildan hozirgi kungacha. Kembrij universiteti matbuoti. 190pp. ISBN  9781107507180.
  265. ^ Klaus Muhlhahn, Xitoyni zamonaviy qilish: Buyuk Tsindan Si Tszinpinga (2019) pp 107-119.
  266. ^ Arnold Rayt, Yigirmanchi asrda Hongkong, Shanxay va Xitoyning boshqa shartnoma portlari haqidagi taassurotlar: ularning tarixi, odamlari, tijoratlari, tarmoqlari va manbalari (1908) onlayn
  267. ^ Erik Baark, Lightning Wires: The Telegraph and China's Technological Modernization 1860-1890 (ABC-CLIO/Greenwood, 1997)
  268. ^ Ariane Knuesel, "British diplomacy and the telegraph in nineteenth-century China." Diplomatiya va davlatchilik 18.3 (2007): 517-537.
  269. ^ John King Fairbank, et al. East Asia: Tradition & Transformation (1989) pp. 345, 357, 468–477, 483, 513.
  270. ^ Klaus Muhlhahn, Xitoyni zamonaviy qilish: Buyuk Tsindan Si Tszinpinga (2019) pp 195–199.
  271. ^ Rhoads Murphey, Shanxay: zamonaviy Xitoy uchun kalit (Garvard UP, 2013).
  272. ^ Robert Bikers, "Shanxayliklar: 1843–1937 yillarda Shanxayda inglizlar ko'chmanchilar jamoasining shakllanishi va o'ziga xosligi". O'tmish va hozirgi 159.1 (1998): 161–211 onlayn.
  273. ^ Yen-p'ing Hao, O'n to'qqizinchi asrdagi Xitoyning tijorat inqilobi: Xitoy-G'arbiy Merkantil raqobatining ko'tarilishi (U California Press, 1984).
  274. ^ Muhlhahn, Xitoyni zamonaviy qilish 110–114.
  275. ^ Frank H.H. King va boshq., Hongkong va Shanxay bank korporatsiyasi tarixi (Kembrij UP, 1991).
  276. ^ Devid Maklin, "Xitoy temir yo'llari va 1903 yilgi Taunli shartnomasi". Zamonaviy Osiyo tadqiqotlari 7.2 (1973): 145-164 onlayn
  277. ^ Fransua Gipulu, tahr. Osiyo O'rta er dengizi: XIII-XXI asrlarda Xitoy, Yaponiya va Janubiy Osiyodagi port shaharlari va savdo tarmoqlari (Elgar, 2011).
  278. ^ Natascha Vittinghoff, "Oxirgi Tsin Xitoyida (1860-1880) jamoatchilik ovozi va zamonaviy matbuotning paydo bo'lishi uchun tanlovda o'quvchilar, noshirlar va rasmiylar". T'oung Pao 87.4 (2001): 393-455 onlayn.
  279. ^ Muhlhahn, Xitoyni zamonaviy qilish, p. 115.
  280. ^ Filipp L. Vikeri, tahrir. Xristianlar xitoy madaniyati bilan uchrashadilar: Xitoyda Anglikan va Episkopal tarixiga oid insholar (Hong Kong University Press, 2015).
  281. ^ Chow Tse-Tsung, To'rtinchi may harakati: zamonaviy Xitoyda intellektual inqilob (Garvard UP. 1960) 228-238 betlar. onlayn
  282. ^ John C. DeKorne, "Sun Yat-Sen va maxfiy jamiyatlar". Tinch okeani bilan bog'liq ishlar 7.4 (1934): 425-433 onlayn.

Manbalar

  • Compilation Group for the "History of Modern China" Series. (2000). Afyun urushi. Honolulu: University Press of the Pacific; reprint from 1976 edition. ISBN  0898751500.
  • Allen, Robert (2009), "Agricultural productivity and rural incomes in England and the Yangtze Delta, c. 1620–c. 1820" (PDF), Iqtisodiy tarix sharhi, 62 (3): 525–50, CiteSeerX  10.1.1.149.5916, doi:10.1111 / j.1468-0289.2008.00443.x, S2CID  153993424, dan arxivlangan asl nusxasi (PDF) 2010-09-20, olingan 2010-07-28
  • Atwell, William (1998), "Ming China and the emerging world economy, c. 1470–1650", in Twitchett, Denis; Mote, Frederick W. (eds.), The Cambridge History of China: Volume 8: The Ming Dynasty: 1368–1644, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 376–416, ISBN  978-0521243339
  • Atwell, William S. (2002), "Time, Money, and the Weather: Ming China and the "Great Depression" of the Mid-Fifteenth Century", Osiyo tadqiqotlari jurnali, 61 (1): 83–113, doi:10.2307/2700190, JSTOR  2700190
  • Bagley, Robert (1999), "Shang Archaeology", in Loewe, Michael; Shaughnessy, Edward L. (eds.), From the Origins of Civilization to 221 B.C., The Cambridge History of Ancient China, 1, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 124–231, ISBN  9780521470308
  • Benn, Charlz (2002), Xitoyning Oltin asri: Tan sulolasidagi kundalik hayot, Oksford: Oksford universiteti matbuoti, ISBN  978-0-19-517665-0
  • Bielenstein, Hans (1987), "Wang Mang, the Restoration of the Han Dynasty, and Later Han", in Twitchett, Denis; Feyrbank, Jon K. (tahr.), The Ch'in and Han Empires, 221 B.C. – A.D. 220, Xitoyning Kembrij tarixi, 1, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 223–90, ISBN  978-0521243278
  • Bodde, Derk (1956), "Feudalism in China", in Coulborn Rushton (ed.), Feudalism in History, Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, pp. 49–92, 404–07
  • Bodde, Derk (1987), "The State and Empire of Qin", in Twitchett, Denis; Feyrbank, Jon K. (tahr.), The Ch'in and Han Empires, 221 B.C. – A.D. 220, Xitoyning Kembrij tarixi, 1, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 20–103, ISBN  978-0521243278
  • Bray, Francesca (1984), Biology and Biological Technology: Agriculture, Science and Civilisation in China, VI: 2, Kembrij: Kembrij universiteti matbuoti
  • Bruk, Timoti (1998), Lazzatlanishning chalkashliklari: Xitoy Xitoyidagi savdo va madaniyat, Berkli: Kaliforniya universiteti matbuoti, ISBN  978-0-520-22154-3
  • Chang, Kvang-chih (1999), "China on the Eve of the Historical Period", in Loewe, Michael; Shaughnessy, Edward L. (eds.), From the Origins of Civilization to 221 B.C., The Cambridge History of Ancient China, 1, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 37–73, ISBN  9780521470308
  • Dardess, John (1995), "Shun-Ti and the end of Yuan rule in China", in Twitchett, Denis; Franke, Herbert (eds.), Alien regimes and Border States, 710–1368, Xitoyning Kembrij tarixi, 6, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 561–88, ISBN  9780521243315
  • Dreyer, Edward H. (1988), "Military origins of Ming China", in Twitchett, Denis; Mote, Frederick W. (eds.), The Ming Dynasty, part 1, Xitoyning Kembrij tarixi, 7, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 58–107, ISBN  9780521243322
  • Du, Wenyu (1998), "Tang Song Jingji Shili Bijiao Yanjiu" [Comparative Study of Tang and Song Dynasty's Economic Strength] (PDF), Researches in Chinese Economic History, 1998 (4), ISSN  1002-8005, dan arxivlangan asl nusxasi (PDF) 2011-09-29 kunlari, olingan 2010-07-26
  • Ebrey, Patricia Buckley (1986), "The Economic and Social History of Later Han", in Twitchett, Denis; Feyrbank, Jon K. (tahr.), The Ch'in and Han Empires, 221 B.C. – A.D. 220, Cambridge History of China, 1, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 608–48, ISBN  978-0521243278
  • Ebrey, Patricia Buckley (1993), Xitoy tsivilizatsiyasi: manbalar kitobi, Nyu-York: Simon va Shuster, ISBN  978-0029087527
  • Ebrey, Patricia Buckley (1999), Xitoyning Kembrijdagi tasvirlangan tarixi, Kembrij: Kembrij universiteti matbuoti, ISBN  978-0-521-43519-2
  • Ebrey, Patricia; Uoltoll, Enn; Palais, James (2006), Sharqiy Osiyo: madaniy, ijtimoiy va siyosiy tarix, Boston: Houghton Mifflin Company, ISBN  978-0-618-13384-0
  • Embri, Ainsli Tomas (1997), G'arbiy va jahon tarixidagi Osiyo: o'qitish uchun qo'llanma, Armonk: ME Sharpe, Inc
  • Endicott-West, Elizabeth (1989), "Merchant Associations in Yüan China: The 'Ortoy'", Osiyo katta, 2, Academia Sinica, pp. 127–154, JSTOR  41645438.
  • Essex instituti (1895), "Commerce and Trade", Books on China in the Library of the Essex Institute, Salem, Massachusets, AQSh
  • Feyrbank, Jon K. (1978), "Introduction: The old order", in Fairbank John K. (ed.), Oxirgi Ching 1800–1911, 1-qism, Xitoyning Kembrij tarixi, 10, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 1–35, ISBN  9780521214476
  • Fairbank, John K. (1978), "The Canton trade and the Opium War", in Fairbank John K. (ed.), Oxirgi Ching 1800–1911, 1-qism, Xitoyning Kembrij tarixi, 10, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 163–213, ISBN  9780521214476
  • Fairbank, John K. (1978), "The creation of the Treaty System", in Fairbank John K. (ed.), Oxirgi Ching 1800–1911, 1-qism, Xitoyning Kembrij tarixi, 10, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 213–64, ISBN  9780521214476
  • Feyrbank, Jon K .; Goldman, Merle (2006), China: A New History (2nd Enlarged ed.), Harvard: Harvard University Press, ISBN  978-0-674-01828-0
  • Franke, Herbert (1994), "The Chin Dynasty", in Franke, Herbert; Twitchett, Denis (eds.), Alien Regimes and Border States, 710–1368, Xitoyning Kembrij tarixi, 6, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 215–319, ISBN  9780521243315
  • Gernet, Jacques (1962), Daily Life in China on the Eve of the Mongol Invasion, 1250–1276, Stanford: Stanford University Press, ISBN  978-0-8047-0720-6
  • Heijdra, Martin (1998), "The socio-economic development of rural China during the Ming", in Mote, Frederick W.; Twitchett, Denis (eds.), Min sulolasi, 1368–1644, 1-qism, Xitoyning Kembrij tarixi, 8, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 417–578, ISBN  978-0521243339
  • Hinsch, Bret (2002), Women in Imperial China, Lanxem: Rovman va Littlefild, ISBN  978-0742518728
  • Hobson, John M. (2004), The Eastern Origins of Western Civilisation, Kembrij universiteti matbuoti, ISBN  978-0-521-54724-6
  • Hsiao, Ch'i-Ch'ing (1994), "Mid-Yuan politics", in Franke, Herbert; Twitchett, Denis (eds.), Alien Regimes and Border States, 710–1368, Xitoyning Kembrij tarixi, 6, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 490–561, ISBN  9780521243315
  • Xsu, Cho-yun (1999), "The Spring and Autumn period", in Loewe, Michael; Shaughnessy, Edward L. (eds.), From the Origins of Civilization to 221 B.C., The Cambridge History of Ancient China, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 545–86, ISBN  9780521470308
  • Xuang, Rey (1998), "Min fiskal ma'muriyati", Tvitchet shahrida, Denis; Feyrbank, Jon K. (tahr.), Min sulolasi, 1 398–1644, 2-qism, Xitoyning Kembrij tarixi, 8, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 106–72, ISBN  9780521243339
  • Dji, Tszianxun; va boshq. (2005a), Xitoy tarixi ensiklopediyasi (in Chinese), 1, Pekin nashriyoti, ISBN  978-7900321541
  • Dji, Tszianxun; va boshq. (2005b), Xitoy tarixi ensiklopediyasi (in Chinese), 2, Pekin nashriyoti, ISBN  978-7900321541
  • Dji, Tszianxun; va boshq. (2005), Xitoy tarixi ensiklopediyasi (in Chinese), 3, Pekin nashriyoti, ISBN  978-7900321541
  • Ji, Xianlin (1997), History of Cane Sugar in China, Eastern Culture and economy publishers, ISBN  978-7-80127-284-3
  • Keightley, David N. (1999), "The Shang: China's First Historical Dynasty", in Loewe, Michael; Shaughnessy, Edward L. (eds.), From the Origins of Civilization to 221 B.C., The Cambridge History of Ancient China, 1, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 232–91, ISBN  9780521470308
  • Kuhn, Dieter (1982), "The Silk Workshops of the Shang Dynasty (16th–11th Century B.C.)", in Guohao, Li; va boshq. (tahr.), Explorations in the History of Science and Technology in China, in Honour of the Eightieth Birthday of Dr. Joseph Needham, Shanghai: Guji chubanshe, pp. 367–408
  • Kuhn, Dieter (1988), To'qimachilik texnologiyasi: yigiruv va burama, Science and Civilisation in China, V:9, Kembrij: Kembrij universiteti matbuoti
  • Lewis, Mark Edward (1999), "Warring States: Political History", in Loewe, Michael; Shaughnessy, Edward L. (eds.), From the Origins of Civilization to 221 B.C., The Cambridge History of Ancient China, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 587–650, ISBN  9780521243339
  • Li, Bo; Zheng, Yin (2001), 5000 yillik Xitoy tarixi (xitoy tilida), Ichki Mo'g'ul xalqining nashriyot korpusi, ISBN  978-7-204-04420-7
  • Li, Xueqin (editor-in-chief) (2007), Xizhou shi yu Xizhou wenming 西周史與西周文明 ["The History and Culture of the Western Zhou"], Shanghai: Shanghai kexue jishu wenxian chubanshe 上海科學技術問現出版社
  • Liang, Fangchong (1981), 十四世纪上半叶中国手工业的生产力和生产关系的矛盾, Shaanxi People's publishers, archived from asl nusxasi 2010-03-02 da, olingan 2010-08-11
  • Loewe, Michael (1986), "Former Han Dynasty", in Twitchett, Denis; Feyrbank, Jon K. (tahr.), The Ch'in and Han Empires, 221 B.C. – A.D. 220, Cambridge History of China, 1, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 103–223, ISBN  978-0521243278
  • Maddison, Angus (2007), Chinese economic performance in the long run, Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development. Development Centre, ISBN  9789264037625
  • Micklethwait, John (2003), The Company: A Short History of a Revolutionary Idea, Modern Library Chronicles, Zamonaviy kutubxona, ISBN  978-0812972870
  • Milanovic, Branco (2003), Against globalization as we know it, Elsevier Science Ltd. World Development Vol. 31, No. 4, pp. 667–683
  • Mote, Frederick W. (1988), "Introduction", in Twitchett, Denis; Mote, Frederick W. (eds.), The Ming Dynasty, part 1, Xitoyning Kembrij tarixi, 7, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 1–11, ISBN  9780521243322
  • Mühlhahn, Klaus. Xitoyni zamonaviy qilish: Buyuk Tsindan Si Tszinpinga (Harvard UP. 2019)
  • Myers, H. Ramon; Wang, Yeh-Chien (2002), "Economic developments, 1644-1800", in Peterson Willard J. (ed.), Part One: The Ch'ing Empire to 1800, Xitoyning Kembrij tarixi, 9, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 563–647, ISBN  9780521243346
  • Nidxem, Jozef; Tsuen-Hsuin, Tsien (1985), Xitoyda fan va tsivilizatsiya, 5:1, Kembrij: Kembrij universiteti matbuoti, ISBN  9780521086905
  • Nishijima, Sadao (1986), "Sobiq Xanning iqtisodiy va ijtimoiy tarixi", Tvitset shahrida, Denis; Feyrbank, Jon K. (tahr.), The Ch'in and Han Empires, 221 B.C. – A.D. 220, Cambridge History of China, 1, Kembrij: Kembrij universiteti matbuoti, 545–607 betlar, ISBN  978-0521243278
  • Pomeranz, Kenneth (2000), The Great Divergence: China, Europe, and the Making of the Modern World Economy, Prinston universiteti matbuoti, ISBN  978-0-691-09010-8
  • Qi Xia (1999), Zhongguo jing ji tong shi. Song dai jing ji juan 中国经济通史. 宋代经济卷 ["General Economic History of China – The Economy of the Song Dynasty"] (in Chinese), 1:2, Economic Daily Publishers, ISBN  978-7-80127-462-5
  • Rickett, Adele (1987), "Biography of Derk Bodde", in Le Blanc, Charles; Blader Susan (eds.), Xitoyning tabiat va jamiyat haqidagi g'oyalari: Derk Bodde sharafiga bag'ishlangan tadqiqotlar, Hong Kong: Hong Kong University Press, pp. 1–20
  • Rossabi, Morris (1988), Khubilai Khan: His Life and Times, Berkli: Kaliforniya universiteti matbuoti, ISBN  978-0-520-05913-9
  • Rossabi, Morris (1995), "The reign of Khubilai Khan", in Twitchett, Denis; Franke, Herbert (eds.), Alien regimes and Border States, Xitoyning Kembrij tarixi, 6, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 414–90, ISBN  9780521243315
  • Schafer, Edward H (1985) [1963], Samarqandning oltin shaftoli: T'ang Exotics-ni o'rganish (1st paperback ed.), Berkeley and Los Angeles.: University of California Press, ISBN  978-0-520-05462-2
  • Shaughnessy, Edward L. (1999), "Western Zhou History", in Loewe, Michael; Shaughnessy, Edward L. (eds.), From the Origins of Civilization to 221 B.C., The Cambridge History of Ancient China, 1, Kembrij: Kembrij universiteti matbuoti, ISBN  9780521470308
  • Smith, Paul J. (1993), "State Power and Economic Activism during the New Policies, 1068–1085' The Tea and Horse Trade and the 'Green Sprouts' Loan Policy", in Hymes Robert P. (ed.), Ordering the World : Approaches to State and Society in Sung Dynasty China, Berkeley: Berkeley University of California Press, pp. 76–128, ISBN  9780520076914
  • Spence, Jonathan D. (1999), The Search For Modern China (2nd ed.), New York: W. W. Norton & Company, ISBN  978-0-393-97351-8
  • Sun, Jian (2000), Economic history of China, (1840–1949) (in Chinese), 2, China People's University Press, ISBN  978-7300029535
  • Tanner, Harold Miles (2010), Xitoy: Neolit ​​davri madaniyatlaridan Buyuk Tsing imperiyasi orqali miloddan avvalgi 10000 - 1799 yillar, Hackett Publishing, p. 368, ISBN  978-1-60384-564-9CS1 maint: ref = harv (havola)
  • Von Glahn, Richard (2016), The Economic History of China: From Antiquity to the Nineteenth Century, Kembrij: Kembrij universiteti matbuoti.
  • Wu, Sun; Griffith, Samuel B. (translator) (2006), Urush san'ati, Blue Heron Books, ISBN  978-1897035351
  • Wagner, Donald B. (2001a), "The Administration of the Iron Industry in Eleventh-Century China", Sharqning iqtisodiy va ijtimoiy tarixi jurnali, 44 (2): 175–97, doi:10.1163/156852001753731033
  • Wagner, Donald B. (2001b), Xan Xitoydagi davlat va temir sanoati, Copenhagen: Nordic Institute of Asian Studies Publishing, ISBN  978-8787062831
  • Vakeman, Frederik (1985), Buyuk korxona: XVII asrdagi Xitoyda imperatorlik tartibini manjurlik bilan tiklash, Berkli va Los-Anjeles: Kaliforniya universiteti matbuoti, ISBN  978-0520048041
  • Xie, Yuanlu (2005), "Tang-Song ijtimoiy-iqtisodiy o'zgarishini tahlil qilish", Research on Chinese Economic History, 2, dan arxivlangan asl nusxasi 2011-07-06 da, olingan 2010-08-08
  • Xu, Huan (2005), "The development of South China's economy during the six dynasties", South China's social and economic adevelopment Yo'qolgan yoki bo'sh sarlavha = (Yordam bering)
  • Zhan, Zhifei (2006), "Xan boshidagi pul tizimidagi o'zgarishlar va uning ta'siri", Iqtisodiy tarix, 5

Qo'shimcha o'qish

  • Brandt, Loren, Debin Ma, and Thomas G. Rawski. "From divergence to convergence: reevaluating the history behind China's economic boom." Iqtisodiy adabiyotlar jurnali 52.1 (2014): 45-123. onlayn
  • Deng, Kent, and Patrick O'Brien. "Establishing statistical foundations of a chronology for the great divergence: a survey and critique of the primary sources for the construction of relative wage levels for Ming–Qing China." Iqtisodiy tarixni ko'rib chiqish 69.4 (2016): 1057-1082.
  • Feuerwerker, Albert. China’s early industrialization: Sheng Hsuan-Huai (1844–1916) and mandarin enterprise(Harvard UP, 1958) onlayn.
  • Feuerwerker, Albert. The Chinese Economy, Ca. 1870–1911 (Michigan Papers in Chinese Studies No. 5), University of Michigan, 1969 onlayn
  • Feuerwerker, Albert. The Chinese Economy, 1912–1949. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1968 onlayn
  • Feuerwerker, Albert. "The state and the economy in late imperial China." Theory and Society 13.3 (1984): 297-326 onlayn.
  • Feuerwerker, Albert. "Economic trends in the late Ch’ing empire, 1870–1911." yilda The Cambridge History of China 11.part 2 (1980): 1–69.
  • Feuerwerker, Albert. “Handicraft and Manufactured Cotton Textiles in China, 1871-1910.” Iqtisodiy tarix jurnali 30#2 1970, pp. 338–378. onlayn
  • Goldstone, Jack A. "Efflorescences and economic growth in world history: rethinking the" Rise of the West" and the Industrial Revolution." Journal of world history (2002): 323-389. onlayn; emphasis on China
  • Kaminishi, Miriam, and Andrew David Smith. "Western Debates About Chinese Entrepreneurship in the Treaty Port Period, 1842–1911" Enterprise & Society 21#1 (March 2020), pp. 134-169, online.
  • Keller, Wolfgang, and Carol H. Shiue. "China's Foreign Trade and Investment, 1800-1950" (National Bureau of Economic Research, 2020) onlayn
  • King, Frank H. H. A concise economic history of modern China (1840-1961) (1961) onlayn
  • Lee, Mabel Ping Hua. The Economic History of China: With special reference to agriculture (Columbia UP, 1921) onlayn
  • Madison, Angus. Chinese economic performance in the long run (1998) DOI:10.5860/choice.45-6299 onlayn
  • Mann, Syuzan. Local merchants and the Chinese bureaucracy, 1750-1950 (Stanford UP, 1987).
  • Myers, R. The Chinese Peasant Economy: Agricultural Development in Hopei and Shantung 1890–1949 (Harvard UP, 1970)
  • O'Brayen, Patrik Karl. The Economies of Imperial China and Western Europe: Debating the Great Divergence (2020) parcha
  • Perkins, Dwight, ed. China’s modern economy in historical perspective (Stanford UP, 1975).
  • Swamy, Subramanian. “The Response to Economic Challenge: A Comparative Economic History of China and India, 1870-1952.” Har chorakda Iqtisodiyot jurnali 93#1 1979, pp. 25–46. onlayn

Tarixnoma

  • Fairbank, John K., et al. “Economic Change in Early Modern China: An Analytic Framework.” Iqtisodiy rivojlanish va madaniy o'zgarishlar 9#1 1960, pp. 1–26. onlayn
  • Horesh, Niv. "The Pendulum Swings Again: Recent Debates on China's Prewar Economy." Xalqaro Osiyo tadqiqotlari jurnali 6.2 (2009): 201-217.
  • Huang, Philip C. C. “The Paradigmatic Crisis in Chinese Studies: Paradoxes in Social and Economic History.” Zamonaviy Xitoy 17#3 1991, pp. 299–341. onlayn
  • Rawski, Evelyn S. "Research Themes in Ming-Qing Socioeconomic History--The State of the Field." Osiyo tadqiqotlari jurnali 50.1 (1991): 84-111. onlayn
  • Rawski, Thomas G., and Lillian M. Li, eds. Chinese History in Economic Perspective (U of California Press, 1992). onlayn

Tashqi havolalar